Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

JOURNALISM IN THE ATTENTION ECONOMY: the relation between digital platforms and news organizations1

O JORNALISMO NA ECONOMIA DA ATENÇÃO: a relação entre plataformas digitais e organizações jornalísticas

EL PERIODISMO EN LA ECONOMÍA DE LA ATENCIÓN: la relación entre plataformas digitales y organizaciones periodísticas

ABSTRACT

This article analyzes the relationship between news organizations and the digital platforms Facebook and Google, based on the attention economy and the concept of audience commodity. The article explains the way these organizations currently compete in the attention market. It sets out how the Silicon Valley companies have acquired a central and dominant position in the distribution of informative content by capturing the attention of users, and, therefore, the sale of the audience as a commodity. This situation has affected the advertising-revenue-based business model of news organizations.

Key words
Attention economy; Journalism; Facebook ; Google; Audience-commodity

RESUMO

O artigo analisa a relação entre organizações jornalísticas e plataformas digitais como Facebook e Google. Com base na economia da atenção e no conceito de audiência-mercadoria, expõe-se como, no atual mercado da atenção, as empresas do Vale do Silício conquistaram uma posição dominante na distribuição de conteúdos informativos, captando a atenção dos consumidores e, portanto, a venda de audiência-mercadoria. A situação tem afetado o modelo de negócios das empresas jornalísticas que baseiam suas receitas na publicidade.

Palavras-chave
Economia da atenção; Jornalismo; Facebook ; Google; Audiência-mercadoria

RESUMEN

El presente artículo analiza la relación entre organizaciones periodísticas y plataformas digitales como Facebook y Google. A partir de la economía de la atención y el concepto de audiencia-mercancía, se expone cómo en el actual mercado de la atención las compañías de Silicon Valley han adquirido una posición central y dominante en la distribución de contenidos informativos, capturando la atención de los usuarios y, por ende, la venta de audiencia-mercancía. Esta situación ha afectado el modelo de negocio de las organizaciones periodísticas que basan sus ingresos en la publicidad.

Palabras clave
Economía de la atención; Periodismo; Facebook ; Google; Audiencia-mercancía

1 Introduction

Journalism and the news industry are going through a transformation period in which it has been necessary to rethink the way content is produced and distributed, its relation with the audience, and how to deal with public opinion. In that sense, it is common to hear that journalism is in crisis. Lack of innovation and adaptation to the digital world, the way that the business model has become obsolete, loss of credibility in the media among others are referred to as possible causes for this crisis (Ramonet, 2012Ramonet, I. (2012). La explosión del periodismo. Internet pone en jaque a los medios tradicionales. Bogotá: Le Monde diplomatic.).

The internet runs like a red line through this crisis. At first, the arrival of the web was received with enthusiasm by the journalism world because it facilitated the production of, distribution of, and access to content. Through blogs and social media, more people became involved in the development of news, stimulating conversation and debates about topics of general interest. However, two decades later, most of that enthusiasm has vanished and today it is more common to talk about the internet as a threat to journalism. We went from an era of participation into an era of populism and fake news (Anderson, 2020Anderson, C. (2020). The State(s) of Things. 20 Years of Journalism Studies and Political Communication. Comunicazione política, 21(1), 47-62. DOI: 10.3270/96422
https://doi.org/10.3270/96422...
).

This crisis cannot only be seen from one point of view. According to Barbie Zelizer (2015)Zelizer, B. (2015). Terms of Choice: Uncertainty, Journalism, and Crisis. Journal of Communication, 65(5), 888–908. DOI: 10.1111/jcom.12157
https://doi.org/10.1111/jcom.12157...
, journalism is facing different types of crises; political, economic, moral, occupational, social, and technological. Although the writer’s analysis focuses on journalism in the United States, her reflection invites consideration of the changes in journalism from different angles. That is why the objective of this article is to take a closer look at the relation between news organizations and digital businesses like Facebook and Google from the attention economy perspective (Goldhaber, 1996Goldhaber, M. (1997). The Attention Economy on the Net. First Monday, 2(4). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v2i4.519...
) and its link to the audience commodity concept (Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
). In brief, this article will discuss which parts of the crisis in the business model of news organizations are due to the monopoly Facebook and Google have obtained in content distribution.

The analysis focuses on Google and Facebook for two reasons: i) of the four big international tech companies often known as GAFA (Google, Amazon, Facebook, Apple), Facebook and Google are the ones whose main source of revenue is advertising2 2 On a global level, Google and Facebook hold 55% of the advertising revenue. See: Statista. (2019). Digital Economy compass. Retrieved from www.statista.com/study/52194/digital-economy-compass/ . ii) According to global studies, Facebook and Google are the main sources through which audiences access journalistic content (Newman et al., 2019Newman, N., Fletcher, R., Kalogeropoulos, A., & Nielsen, R. (2019) Digital News Report 2019. Oxford: Reuters Institute. Retrieved from www.digitalnewsreport.org/
www.digitalnewsreport.org/...
).

One thing that needs to be clarified is the concept of platforms. In common and specialized language, technological companies (Facebook, Google, Uber, Airbnb) are referred to as platforms. However, caution is required when using this term, as usually, neutrality is one of the main characteristics of a platform (Dijck et al., 2018Dijck, J. van, Poell, T., & Waal, M. (2018). The platform society: Public values in a connective world. New York, Oxford University Press.; Gillespie, 2010Gillespie, T. (2010). The politics of ‘platforms’. New Media & Society, 12(3), 347–364. DOI: 10.1177/1461444809342738
https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444809342738...
); that is why the word platform stands for an intermediary in which interested parties come together and interact. That means that for example, Uber is not a transport company, but a platform that allows users and drivers to come together. Facebook facilitates communication between people, while Google provides a space in which users can access the information they are looking for. By this logic, “platforms are digital infrastructures that enable two or more groups to interact. They, therefore, position themselves as intermediaries that bring together different users” (Srnicek, 2018Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas. Buenos Aires: Caja Negra., p.46). However, “While often presenting themselves as empty spaces for others to interact on, they in fact embody a politics. The rules of product and service development, as well as marketplace interactions, are set by the platform owner” (Srnicek, 2018Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas. Buenos Aires: Caja Negra., p.48).

Platforms are not neutral, nor are they egalitarian spaces in which everyone participates under the same conditions; they have particular interests that condition their operation and also which groups interact within them (Dijck et al., 2018Dijck, J. van, Poell, T., & Waal, M. (2018). The platform society: Public values in a connective world. New York, Oxford University Press.). That is why, when the word platform is used throughout this article, it refers to tech companies, but by no means to neutral spaces free of interests. On the contrary, this article highlights the high level of intermediation they have acquired, which has strongly affected the business models of news organizations.

2 Media and platforms: the paradox of a relationship built on dependency

One of the most important digital innovations on a worldwide level was the appearance of businesses like Google and Facebook (Pariser, 2017Pariser, E. (2017). El filtro burbuja. Cómo la red decide lo que leemos y lo que pensamos. Barcelona: Taurus.; Galloway, 2018Galloway, S. (2018). Four. El ADN secreto de Amazon, Apple, Facebook y Google. Barcelona: Penguin Random House.). Their arrival inspired hope and expectations, as they improved access to content and an exchange of ideas that contributed to the spread of knowledge and could lead to better-informed societies.

As Google and Facebook grew, they gained more influence in fields like education, politics, health, and others (Dijck et al., 2018Dijck, J. van, Poell, T., & Waal, M. (2018). The platform society: Public values in a connective world. New York, Oxford University Press.). One of the sectors they quickly conquered was journalism because Google and Facebook made a direct contribution to getting the news to people and more places. They improved access and the level of audience engagement and participation. If journalism had limitations, these companies could improve them. That is why, “in recent years, hope was often expressed that digital platforms for publishing and distributing content could offer a new path for journalism” (Nechushtai, 2018Nechushtai, E. (2018). Could digital platforms capture the media through infrastructure? Journalism, 19(8), 1043–1058. DOI: 10.1177/1464884917725163
https://doi.org/10.1177/1464884917725163...
, p.1044).

The idea that Google and Facebook would strengthen traditional media meant they emerged as allies of journalism (Jarvis, 2015Jarvis, J. (2015). El fin de los medios de comunicación de masa. México: Paidós.). Thanks to those companies, radio, television, and press would reach a much bigger audience than through their traditional distribution channels3 3 Part of the hope was that alternative digital media that would transform the news industry. Buzzfeed, a digital media outlet from the United States founded by Jonah Peretti exemplified the way that this new type of journalism could use technology to reach bigger audiences. In 2014, Peretti announced a new golden age for news organizations and journalism. Retrieved from https://medium.com/@peretti/is-history-repeating-itself-33390aeb6cd9 . “The hope was that the convergence of social media and journalism would create a superior version or hybrid of both; a rich network populated by useful and timely information” (Bell & Owen, 2017Bell, E., & Owen, T. (2017). The platform press. How Silicon Valley reengineered journalism. New York: Columbia Journalism School., p.14).

This potential made it seem like a great idea to use Facebook and Google. That was the reason why news organizations quickly created profiles on Facebook and indexed their content on Google. This started a relationship that, as we see it, planted three paradoxes.

The first paradox is that the media did effectively reach a bigger audience, but it didn’t generate more revenue. When audiences access and consume information through Facebook and Google, the tech companies get the user data; which means they are the ones that can sell data and advertising space and time: “The architecture that enables news organizations to reach their audiences on social platforms also militates against their sustainability” (Bell & Owen, 2017Bell, E., & Owen, T. (2017). The platform press. How Silicon Valley reengineered journalism. New York: Columbia Journalism School., pp.15–16). It took news organizations a while to notice that reaching a bigger audience did not mean higher revenue.

Being on Facebook or Google seemed beneficial. The fact that users were accessing content on their webpages generated traffic, which meant there was a possibility to embed advertising. That seemed a reasonable deal. However, the reality was very different; traffic did not grow as much as the news organizations expected (Ju et al., 2014Ju, A., Jeong, S., & Chyi, I. (2014). Will social media save newspapers? Examining the effectiveness of Facebook and Twitter as news platform. Journalism Practice, 8(1), 1–17. DOI: 10.1080/17512786.2013.794022
https://doi.org/10.1080/17512786.2013.79...
). The lack of expected traffic also meant that they did not have consumer data from their readers. This data was collected by the companies through which the content arrived, not the news organizations themselves. By sharing their content through Facebook and Google, they gave these companies the power of distribution and allowed their algorithms to decide who would have a bigger circulation (Myllylahti, 2018Myllylahti, M. (2018) An attention economy trap? An empirical investigation into four news companies’ Facebook traffic and social media revenue. Journal of Media Business Studies, 15(4), 237–253. DOI: 10.1080/16522354.2018.1527521
https://doi.org/10.1080/16522354.2018.15...
, 2020Myllylahti, M. (2020). Paying Attention to Attention: A Conceptual Framework for Studying News Reader Revenue Models Related to Platforms. Digital Journalism, 8(5), 567–575. DOI: 10.1080/21670811.2019.1691926
https://doi.org/10.1080/21670811.2019.16...
).

The second paradox has to do with visibility. If a news organization wants to appear at the top of Google or on more people’s Facebook News Feeds, they would have to pay for it. The quality and relevance of the content are no longer sufficient to gain a bigger reach. It is the companies’ algorithms that give them the power to decide and manipulate what gets more visibility. As such, on top of giving their content to these companies, news organizations would have to pay the platforms for their content to be seen by more people. That’s why, as journalist Diego SalazarSalazar, D. (2019). No hemos entendido nada. Barcelona: Debate. states in his book “No hemos entendido nada” (We haven’t understood anything), Facebook and Google “didn’t just take over their [news organizations] distribution platform, they didn’t just force them to create free content to distribute on their platforms [...], they also convinced/obliged them to pay for its visibility (2019, p.228, our translation).

The third paradox is about the audience. If news organizations want to get to know their audience, they have to use the platforms. In other words, news organizations have to turn to Facebook or Google so that they can get to know their readers. Since they have the power of distribution and the tools that track and measure user behavior, Facebook and Google have all the data. The holder of that data has more power with advertisers. “Via platform-administered tools, free audience analytics, and programmatic ad-bidding, Google and Facebook are now the gatekeepers to the rich analytics publishers need to understand their audiences” (Tow Center for Digital Journalism, 2018Tow Center for Digital Journalism. (2018). Friend & Foe: The Platform Press at the Heart of Journalism. New York, Columbia Journalism School., p.96).

By giving away power of distribution, news organizations did not just lose autonomy over their content, but also their relationship with their audiences:

Search engines and social media empower news media organizations by offering them new opportunities for reaching people. But they also challenge the privileged position news media organizations have historically occupied because working with them involves losing control over channels of communication and raises the risk of becoming dependent on new intermediaries.

(Nielsen & Ganter, 2018Nielsen, R., & Ganter, S. (2018). Dealing with digital intermediaries: A case study of the relations between publishers and platforms. New Media & Society, 20(4), 1600–1617. DOI: 10.1177/1461444817701318
https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444817701318...
, p.1601).

News media organizations were not aware of the dependency they were establishing with these platforms; but when the advertising revenue of the media decreased and that of the tech companies increased, it became evident that Facebook and Google were not their allies. In fact, the opposite was true; they were competitors. Facebook’s objective is not that their users are better informed, just as Google is not interested in their users receiving the best quality news; their goal is to collect data and have users spend more time using their services. These companies care about the content because it generates traffic. The quality or type of content is not essential4 4 There are researchers that state that the advertising model from Facebook and Google stimulates the production and circulation of fake news, because it enables websites with false information to monetize their content. See: Braun, J., & Eklund J. (2019). Fake News, Real Money: Ad Tech Platforms, Profit-Driven Hoaxes, and the Business of Journalism. Digital Journalism, 7(1), 1–21. , they are interested in the data, the metadata that is generated by the content; as a consequence, even though others produce it, they will do everything in their power to have the content go through their platforms.

This situation has played a big part in the crisis faced by journalism today because even though news organizations’ content could be seen by more people, it did not lead to economic benefits (Cagé, 2016Cagé, J. (2016). Salvar los medios de comunicación. Barcelona, Anagrama.). It is impossible to deny that news organizations generate traffic and visitors thanks to Facebook and Google, the trouble is monetizing this traffic. If the user accesses a page through Facebook or Google, it is Facebook or Google who gets the user data.

The relation between digital platforms and news organizations is one of dependency and, in a way, of subordination, because news organizations have started to produce based on Facebook and Google’s algorithms.

These organizations optimized news production and circulation for multisided digital platforms to maximize user traffic and advertising revenue. While for some this strategy has been effective in generating significant user traffic, in economic terms it has not necessarily made these organizations more sustainable businesses.

(Nieborg & Poell, 2018Nieborg, D., & Poell, T. (2018). The platformization of cultural production: Theorizing the contingent cultural commodity. New Media & Society, 20(11), 4275–4292. DOI: 10.1177/1461444818769694
https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444818769694...
, p.4283).

News organizations do not just create news for general interest anymore, but to satisfy algorithms that guarantee them bigger circulation, visibility, and audiences5 5 One of the strategies that has been adopted by some journalism companies to attract visitors is what is known as “clickbait”, which consists of creating eye-catching headlines for users to click and access the content. . That is how news organizations went from being news producers to being content providers for Facebook and Google, something some researchers call “platform dependent” (Nieborg & Poell, 2018Nieborg, D., & Poell, T. (2018). The platformization of cultural production: Theorizing the contingent cultural commodity. New Media & Society, 20(11), 4275–4292. DOI: 10.1177/1461444818769694
https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444818769694...
), or the “platformization” of journalism (Jurno & D’Andréa, 2020Jurno, A., & D’Andréa, C. (2020). Facebook e a plataformização do jornalismo: um olhar para os Instant Articles. Revista Eptic, 22(1), 179–196. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12084
https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/arti...
).

Facebook and Google promoted themselves as a necessity for a news organization, but in reality, news organizations benefitted little and the platforms significantly. “This evolving publisher-platform partnership is unequal. Platforms wield more power over formats and data, and earn significantly more advertising dollars in aggregate than publishers” (Tow Center for Digital Journalism, 2018Tow Center for Digital Journalism. (2018). Friend & Foe: The Platform Press at the Heart of Journalism. New York, Columbia Journalism School., p.25). The power is in the fact that they can collect, process, and analyze the user data to sell to advertisers, data that news organizations barely have access to.

Facebook and Google did not just acquire distribution power; they became editors (Gillespie, 2018Gillespie, T. (2018). Custodians of the internet. Platforms, content moderation, and the hidden decisions that shape social media. New Haven: Yale University Press.; Napoli & Caplan, 2019Napoli, P., & Caplan, R. (2019). Por qué las empresas de medios insisten en que no son empresas de medios, por qué están equivocadas y por qué es importante. Hipertextos, 12(7), 15–46. DOI: 10.24215/23143924e002
https://doi.org/10.24215/23143924e002...
). Through their algorithms, they decide who sees what, and in turn, media are conditioned to work with certain topics and formats to get more visibility. News organizations were subordinated to the logic of Silicon Valley Companies (Siapera, 2013Siapera, E. (2013). Platform infomediation and journalism. Culture Machine, 14, 1–28. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics/
www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics...
) because they needed them “to reach the largest possible number of readers, and to achieve this they have to follow a game whose rules have been made by these platforms” (Marín, 2019Marín, B. (2019). La tiranía del clic. Madrid: Turner., p.32, our translation). The aforementioned reasons mean it is the content distributors, rather than the content producers, who have the power to prioritize what gets a bigger reach; determined by the interests of the owners of the algorithms. That is why every time the platforms change the algorithms, the news organizations are the ones that need to adapt without even really knowing how they work6 6 In 2018, Facebook announced a change in its algorithm to prioritize users over content from journalism companies. This decision generated ire from some news organizations who had adapted their strategies to the existing algorithms, so this modification changed the visibility of journalism products. See: “Facebook drastically changes News Feed to make it ‘good for people’ (and bad for most publishers)” Retrieved from www.niemanlab.org/2018/01/facebook-drastically-changes-news-feed-to-make-it-good-for-people-and-bad-for-most-publishers/?relatedstory Some news organizations opted to not publish their content on this social network. See: “Folha deixa de publicar conteúdo no Facebook”. Retrieved from www1.folha.uol.com.br/poder/2018/02/folha-deixa-de-publicar-conteudo-no-facebook.shtml .

Why are a social network that is there to connect people and a search engine that seeks to organize information competitors for traditional media? Facebook, Google, and traditional media are competitors because their source of revenue is the same: advertising. They are all in the business of capturing the attention to sell it to advertisers7 7 Due to the fall in advertising revenue, many news organizations are exploring new business models to diversify their revenue sources, including subscriptions, donations, events, education, and training programs. See: Jenkins, J. (2020). Publish less, but publish better: pivoting to paid in local news. Oxford: Reuters Institute. See: Tejedor, S., Ventín, A., Cervi, L., Pulido, C., & Tusa, F. (2020). Native Media and Business Models: Comparative Study of 14 Successful Experiences in LatinAmerica. Media and Communication, 8(2), 146–158. DOI:10.17645/mac.v8i2.2712 . This has been the business model of the press since the 19th century, and it is the business model for the tech companies in the 21st century (Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf.). Even though they have different strategies, they share the same marketplace. The differences lie in the mechanisms they use to attract, capture, maintain and measure attention. To attract audiences, news organizations have to invest in quality content, while Facebook and Google do not. They get attention through what others produce, including news organizations.

In theory, Google and Facebook occupy different markets, but in reality, not only do they compete with news organizations, but also with each other. “Google and Facebook have different starting points and different strategies […] but ultimately, they’re competing for the same advertising dollars” (Pariser, 2017Pariser, E. (2017). El filtro burbuja. Cómo la red decide lo que leemos y lo que pensamos. Barcelona: Taurus., p.48). They compete in the audience commodity business, which the following section will show, is the same business as news organizations.

3 Audiences as a commodity

For a long time, mass media believed that content was the only product they could make a profit from. However, over forty years ago, Dallas Smythe (1977)Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
started to question that idea. The author, responsible for the concept of audience commodity, came up with the idea that what mass media of communication are doing when they base their revenue on advertising is to produce an audience that they sell to advertisers.

Until then, it was thought that the media’s commodity was the content itself, “The bourgeois idealist view of the reality of the communication commodity is “messages”, “information”, “images”, “meaning”, “entertainment”, “orientation”, “education”, and “manipulation” (Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
, p.2). Smythe explained that the product was the audience that notices the content instead of the content itself: “What do advertisers buy with their advertising expenditures? […] I suggest that what they buy are the services of audiences with predictable specifications who will pay attention in predictable numbers and at particular times to particular means of communication” (Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
, p.4, emphasis added).

According to Smythe, the function of content was to attract audiences, keep them hooked and then sell them: “The information, entertainment and ‘educational’ material transmitted to the audience is an inducement to recruit potential members of the audience and to maintain their loyal attention” (Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
, p.5, emphasis added).

By Smythe’s definition, all commercial media, whether their content is journalistic, educational, or entertainment, are in the audience commodity business (Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
). Smythe’s ideas generated important discussions back then8 8 An article from Smythe generated an exchange of ideas that became known as “the blindspot debate”. See: Livant, B. (1978). The Audience Commodity: On the “Blindspot Debate”. CTheory, 3(1), 91–106. See: Murdock, G. (1978). Blindspots about western Marxism: A reply to Dallas Smythe. CTheory, 2(2), 109–115. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13744. See: Smythe, D. (1978) Rejoinder to Graham Murdock. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 2(2), 120–127. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13745 , and with the appearance of new players in the cultural and communication industries, Smythe’s approaches have acquired new relevance (Bermejo, 2009Bermejo, F. (2009). Audience manufacture in historical perspective: from broadcasting to Google. New Media & Society, 11(1–2), 133–154. DOI: 10.1177/1461444808099579
https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444808099579...
; Lee, 2011Lee, M. (2011). Google ads and the blindspot debate. Media, Culture & Society, 33(3), 433–447. DOI: 10.1177/0163443710394902
https://doi.org/10.1177/0163443710394902...
; Fuchs, 2012Fuchs, C. (2012). Dallas Smythe Today-The Audience Commodity, the Digital Labour Debate, Marxist Political Economy and Critical Theory. TripleC, 10(2), 692–740. DOI: 10.31269/triplec.v10i2.443
https://doi.org/10.31269/triplec.v10i2.4...
).

Parallel to the development of the internet, new concepts emerged to explain the commercial logic: “the gig economy, the sharing economy, the on-demand economy, the surveillance economy, the app economy, the attention economy, and so on” (Srnicek, 2018Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas. Buenos Aires: Caja Negra., p.40). Although each one of these concepts has followers and opponents, the attention economy has gained notoriety (Goldhaber, 1997Goldhaber, M. (1997). The Attention Economy on the Net. First Monday, 2(4). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v2i4.519...
, 2006; Lanham, 2006Lanham, R. (2006). The economics of attention. Style and substance in the age of information. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.; Kessous et al., 2010Kessous, E., Mellet, K., & Zouinar, M. (2010). L’Économie de l’attention: entre protection des ressources cognitives et extraction de la valeur. Sociologie du Travail, 52(3), 359–373. DOI: 10.4000/sdt.14802
https://doi.org/10.4000/sdt.14802...
; Crogan & Kinsley, 2012Crogan, P., & Kinsley S. (2012). Paying attention: towards a critique of the attention economy. Culture Machine, 13, 1–29. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/...
; Webster, 2014Webster, J. (2014). The marketplace of attention. How audiences take shape in a digital age. Cambridge: MIT Press; Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf.; Nixon, 2017Nixon, B. (2017). Critical Communication Policy Research and the Attention Economy: From Digital Labor Theory to Digital Class Struggle. International Journal of Communication, 11, 4718–4730. Retrieved from www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view/7005
www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view...
; Myllylahti, 2018Myllylahti, M. (2018) An attention economy trap? An empirical investigation into four news companies’ Facebook traffic and social media revenue. Journal of Media Business Studies, 15(4), 237–253. DOI: 10.1080/16522354.2018.1527521
https://doi.org/10.1080/16522354.2018.15...
, 2020Myllylahti, M. (2020). Paying Attention to Attention: A Conceptual Framework for Studying News Reader Revenue Models Related to Platforms. Digital Journalism, 8(5), 567–575. DOI: 10.1080/21670811.2019.1691926
https://doi.org/10.1080/21670811.2019.16...
). In consequence, the attention economy is a useful way to explain the relation between news organizations and Google and Facebook, but this choice is not discretionary. It is useful because as we will discuss later, the media have participated in the attention market from its commercial origins.

For Michael Goldhaber (1997Goldhaber, M. (1997). The Attention Economy on the Net. First Monday, 2(4). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v2i4.519...
, 2006)Goldhaber, M. (2006). The value of openness in an attention economy. First Monday, 11(6). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334...
, one of the first authors to refer to the attention economy to explain the commercial model of the internet, it consists of “a system that revolves primarily around paying, receiving, and seeking what is most intrinsically limited and not replaceable by anything else, namely the attention of other human beings” (Goldhaber, 2006Goldhaber, M. (2006). The value of openness in an attention economy. First Monday, 11(6). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334...
, p.2). The author states that in the information society, what is valued is scarcity, not what is there in abundance, that is why, “information would be an impossible basis for an economy, for one simple reason: economies are governed by what is scarce, and information, especially on the Net, is not only abundant, but overflowing” (Goldhaber, 1997Goldhaber, M. (1997). The Attention Economy on the Net. First Monday, 2(4). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v2i4.519...
, p.2).

Although the concept of the attention economy gained more influence over the past decades and Smythe gave it importance, the idea was initially explored by Herbert A. Simon (1971)Simon, H. (1971) Designing Organizations for an Information Rich World. In M. Greenberger (Ed.), Computers, Communication, and the Public Interest (pp.37–72). Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.. For this writer, “in an information-rich world, the wealth of information means a dearth of something else: a scarcity of whatever it is that information consumes. What information consumes is rather obvious: it consumes the attention of its recipients” (1971, p.40).

Therefore, to continue with the explanation of the attention economy, we have to establish three important characteristics of attention as a resource. First, attention is limited; human beings only have twenty-four hours a day for activities, from those twenty-four hours, ideally, eight are destined to rest, which means that you divide the other sixteen between working, studying, reading, watching television, doing sports, using social media as well as other things. The second characteristic is that it can be measured. Attention is quantifiable by calculating the time that is dedicated to a certain activity. The third characteristic of attention is that by measuring it, it can be monetized. Moreover, the reason to measure it is its economic value. This is what the rating companies have historically done; to calculate the number of people and the amount of time they give their attention to a program to establish the value of the advertising space.

To sum up, our society has information in abundance, so that is not what the economy values. Due to the abundance of information, it is the attention that is scarce and thus economically valued (Lanham, 2006Lanham, R. (2006). The economics of attention. Style and substance in the age of information. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.; Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf.).

The attention economy has become a more important way to explain the digital world. But what this article wants to highlight is that there is a clear relation with the audience commodity concept set out by Smythe. Even the author himself hinted at attention in this footnote:

It is argued by one of my critics that a better term for what advertisers buy would be “attention”. At our present naive stage concerning the matter, it does seem as if attention is indeed what is bought […] Where I refer to audiences as being produced, purchased and used, let it be understood that I mean “audience-power”; however it may turn out upon further realistic analysis to be exercised.

(Smythe, 1977Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheo...
, p.23).

As information and communication technologies developed, the dynamics of markets and business models demonstrated that what is being offered and sold is effectively the attention of audiences. Smythe did not completely agree with this concept because he said that there is no guaranteed attention for the advertisers, as people could be doing other things while adverts were broadcasted. That is why he said that advertisers do not buy attention itself; instead, they pay for a potential audience that might pay attention: “So it matters not if some audience members withdraw their attention; that is expected and discounted in advance by the advertiser” (Smythe, 2006Smythe, D. (2006). On the audience commodity and its work. In M. Durham & D. Kellner (Eds.), Media and cultural studies – Keyworks (pp.230–256). Malden: Blackwell., p.235). Despite this, Smythe’s ideas are still relevant to explain the commercial rationale of the internet and the impact of actors with monopolies on the news industry (Nixon, 2017Nixon, B. (2017). Critical Communication Policy Research and the Attention Economy: From Digital Labor Theory to Digital Class Struggle. International Journal of Communication, 11, 4718–4730. Retrieved from www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view/7005
www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view...
).

4 News organizations in the attention marketplace

News organizations have participated in the attention economy for over a century; the difference is that there is more competition in the 21st century than there was a century or even decades ago. News organizations have been in the attention business since newspapers started printing adverts on their pages in the 19th century.

According to Tim Wu (2017)Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf., the pioneer was New York Sun owner Benjamin Day. Day reckoned they could print adverts in the newspaper to lower the costs:

What Day was contemplating was a break with the traditional strategy for making profit: selling at a price higher than the cost of production. He would instead rely on a different but historically significant business model: reselling the attention of his audience, or advertising. What Day understood was that while his readers may have thought themselves his customers, they were in fact his product.

(Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf., p.12).

The financing of the print press transformed drastically from this point onwards. The space for news was suddenly shared with adverts, the price of a paper dropped. Newspapers reached a bigger audience because it was more important to get more people to see the newspaper, not just for the news, but also for the advertisers.

This model was copied by the media that appeared during the 20th century: radio, television, and later the internet. That is why as these media grew and expanded, so too did the industry of advertising and measurement of audiences. By converting advertising into their main source of income, news organizations started to develop content to actively keep audiences with them, as Smythe explained.

The mechanics of the attention market meant that it was not lucrative to have many informative options; the ideal situation would be to have a limited market with few competitors who could share the money for advertising, a market with few options to divide the attention between. That is why many countries only had a few national and regional newspapers and few radio and television channels. A concentrated market meant that for the majority of the 20th-century news organizations had a monopoly on the attention market. “Legacy revenues and profits reflected the news media’s dominant position in an offline media environment where audiences had low choice and publishers had high market power over advertisers” (Nielsen, 2020Nielsen, R. (2020). Building the Business We Want. In N. Newman (Ed.), Journalism, Media, and Technology Trends and Predictions 2020 (pp.26–27). Oxford: Reuters Institute for the Study of Journalism., p.27).

As the media became dependent on advertising, both media companies and advertisers started looking for ways to measure audience, because the type of ads and cost of advertising depended on the size and characteristics of the audience. Media companies wanted to know how many people paid attention to them, so they could sell their audiences, the advertisers wanted to be sure their products were read, heard, or seen by a certain type and number of people.

In the 1940s, when radio grew as a commercial media, methods to measure audiences started to get developed (Webster, 2014Webster, J. (2014). The marketplace of attention. How audiences take shape in a digital age. Cambridge: MIT Press). Measuring audience was fundamental for the attention economy. The ability to measure it made it a commodity because an audience is worthless if it cannot be quantified; the audience only becomes a commodity when it can be measured.

In their efforts to develop methods to measure audiences, Arthur Nielsen and George Gallup became famous. They had been involved in election polls since the 1930s, and after that, they became famous for the audience measurement. The people meter emerged in the search for reliable methods and was patented by Robert Elder and acquired by Nielsen’s company. The purpose of the people meter was to measure human attention; that means, knowing how many people were paying attention to certain content on radio or television. Although Nielsen took the lead with the people meter, Gallup, a mathematician with a long academic track record, is considered the pioneer in understanding the attention business; according to Derek Thompson (2018, p.260)Thompson, D. (2018). Creadores de hits. La ciencia de la popularidad en la era de la distracción. México, Océano., “Gallup was ahead of his time in understanding that newspapers’ competition didn’t just come from the pulpy inventions of his era, like tabloids and weekly magazines. It came from anything that required the attention of potential readers”.

Measuring audiences gained relevance in the media industry because it established a way to measure the success and impact of content. Despite the innovations in audience measurement methods, the information was still very general, whether for readers, listeners, or viewers. What they knew was the approximate number of people who had their radio or television on at a certain moment or the number of people who said they were reading the newspaper. Nevertheless, this information was enough for media and advertisers. As mentioned before, there was little competition, so it was enough to figure out if one program was seen more than another to know where to advertise.

By setting out the evolution of the business model of news organizations, this article wants to show that news media companies participate in the sale of audience commodities and that companies like Facebook and Google operate under the same logic (Bolaño & Vieira, 2014Bolaño, C., & Vieira, E. (2014). Economía política da internet e os sites de redes sociais, Revista Eptic, 16(2), 71– 84. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/2168
https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/arti...
).

5 Competition for attention

Media used to be a very profitable business model. It had an important space in everyday life, people used it to inform themselves and to be entertained. In other words, people were giving the media industry a lot of their attention. With the expansion of the internet this changed, because part of the time people used to follow the traditional media was replaced by reading blogs, watching YouTube videos, using social media, and other online activities. However you see it, this fragmented users’ attention and took away time they spent on traditional media:

The attention merchants had developed a business model based on directing the public mind toward commercial, well-packaged media products on television. But as the web grew in popularity, people started to pay more attention to one another instead […] The ones suffering for this happy state of affairs were those industries that had spent the past century devising how best to get people to look at them and listen.

(Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf., p.274).

What stayed under the radar for a long time in the news industry was what George Gallup had noted; that the competition was not just other media, it was every activity that captures people’s attention. The competition for attention in a world with an excess of information is a battle with more participants every day. Therefore, first, you battle to get someone’s attention, and then you fight to keep it. In today’s day and age, news organizations compete in a far more intense market. Not only are there more competitors than ever, but two of the competitors are also very powerful.

The business of attention goes further than just capturing and holding it, it is mainly about measuring it. That is possible by gathering audience information; hence, the importance of rating companies during the broadcasting era rises. However, it is not just how much attention is given to content that matters, but also how to obtain and quantify information about the people who consume it. In this respect, Silicon Valley tech companies has an advantage over traditional media, as Facebook and Google have more detailed knowledge about their users. These companies have the infrastructure, resources, and algorithms to trace every movement and convert that into data to create profiles to which they offer targeted advertising. Traditional media consumers barely left any traces; however, in the digital world, every movement can be traced and converted into data.

The companies in Silicon Valley have focused their attention on knowing even the tiniest user movements, intending to develop services and apps designed to ensure users spend more time on them. It is that data that advertisers are interested in, hence “the extracted data moved from being a way to improve services to becoming a way to collect advertising revenues” (Srnicek, 2018Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas. Buenos Aires: Caja Negra., p.53).

Nevertheless, because the wealth of Facebook and Google is the data they possess, they do not sell the actual data (Dantas & Raulino, 2020Dantas, M., & Raulino, G. (2020). Trabalho da audiência e renda informacional no Facebook e no YouTube. Revista Eptic, 22(1), 123–141. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12215
https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/arti...
); “what is sold to advertisers is therefore not the data themselves, but rather the promise that Google’s software will adeptly match an advertiser with the correct users when needed” (Srnicek, 2018Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas. Buenos Aires: Caja Negra., p.56).

This is where digital companies have an advantage over news organizations, the latter have little knowledge about their users, they only have very general information. On the other hand, Facebook and Google know practically everything, not just the news people read, but also, at what time, where, from what device, who they shared it with, and even more detailed information. Hence, “Facebook’s ability to observe their readers while they are reading is every editor’s dream” (Thompson, 2018Thompson, D. (2018). Creadores de hits. La ciencia de la popularidad en la era de la distracción. México, Océano., p.270).

One of the aforementioned paradoxes is that news organizations’ most valuable audience information is in the hands of the platforms. This is why the advertisers choose companies that guarantee very detailed profiles over those that only have general information.

In the pre-digital world, commercial media’s business models consisted of selling audiences, but what they sold was a general idea of an audience; Facebook and Google can sell individuals and highly profiled groups, guaranteeing the advertisers that their product will be seen by whomever they want it to be seen.

Attention merchants had always been ravenous for attention, but now they were gobbling up personal data as well. […] Perhaps the Internet, with its potential to capture every turn of our attention, made this inevitable. Whatever the case, several commercial entities were now compiling ever more detailed dossiers on every man, woman, and child.

(Wu, 2017Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf., p.323).

According to this model, with lots of apps and platforms that occupy people’s time, traditional media gets less and less attention. People spend their time on social networks, where they can also access the content of that same media; and in turn, it becomes even easier for the owners of the digital companies to capture and sell the information. Every time Facebook and Google improve their data collection systems, their advertising revenue will rise. As attention is a limited resource, it is a zero-sum game. If someone wins, someone else loses (Rasmussen, 2007Rasmusen, E. (2007). Games and information. An Introduction to Game Theory. Victoria: Blackwell Publishing.). Therefore, as people spend more time on digital companies’ services, their advertising revenue grows. The money spent on advertising only grows a little, while there are more and more competitors all the time; if some grow exponentially, others will decrease abruptly.

Currently, the companies that produce the best quality content do not have an advantage in the attention marketplace. The companies who that can best collect user information have the advantage, and those are the distribution platforms. That is because they do not only capture attention, they can also shape it in a way that users spend more time on their apps and services. “The process of distribution, of efficiently disseminating information from producers to users and vice versa acquired an increased importance, precisely because this process could be controlled and managed more than the process of production” (Siapera, 2013Siapera, E. (2013). Platform infomediation and journalism. Culture Machine, 14, 1–28. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics/
www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics...
, p.11). Facebook and Google do not just attract attention; they can manipulate it, and develop strategies to keep users connected to their platforms for longer (Bucher, 2012Bucher, T. (2012). A technicity of attention: how software ‘makes sense’. Culture Machine, 13, 1–23. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/...
).

In the current attention marketplace, something that we have never seen in the analog market is happening; monopolistic actors control the entire value chain. In the past, the producers and distributors who offered their content were on one side. On another were the rating companies that established the size of the audiences. And, last were the advertising agencies who determined the value of adverts according to content and size of the audience. Several sectors co-existed and were complementary. Even though they do not produce any content, in the digital world, Facebook and Google have the power over the distribution, they decide who sees what; they define the value of ads, and own the tools that quantify the consumer practice. It is an unprecedented vertical integration.

Nowadays, producers of content are subordinate to monopolistic actors that control distribution in the advertising market. News organizations are still the main producers of news, but they have lost autonomy over how and where it circulates.

6 Discussion

Google and Facebook have affected the news industry worldwide, as they have much power over the circulation, distribution, and consumption of informative content. In this context, news media companies have become platform content providers, working and adapting to their distribution logics.

The attention marketplace is a zero-sum game. If one party wins, others lose, as advertising budgets will be spent where the users are and their data is. In the battle for attention, Google and Facebook have taken the majority of the revenue, while news organizations experienced a decline.

The phrase “content is king” is very important in the entertainment industry, and sometimes that is the case for the news industry. However, this phrase is only partly true, as the content is nothing without distribution channels to reach an audience. In consequence, “content might be king, but distribution is the kingdom” (Thompson, 2018Thompson, D. (2018). Creadores de hits. La ciencia de la popularidad en la era de la distracción. México, Océano., p.18). Who controls the distribution can choose the king. The news organizations have the content but leave the distribution in hands of third parties.

The attention market will not go back to how it was because today’s content comes through different channels and networks. Nevertheless, news organizations should be conscious of these new dynamics to build sustainable business models without depending on or subordinating to intermediaries. Facebook and Google are not neutral observers in the news industry; they are active players with their own interests. The two companies base their business model on advertising, so their purpose is not to satisfy the needs of the producers nor to contribute to a better-informed world; their main objective is to capture, maintain and commercially exploit user attention.

They have indeed been trying to help journalism through initiatives like the Google News Initiative and Facebook Journalism Project, but these initiatives do not offer solutions to structural problems. On top of that, they are part of a public relations campaign to position themselves as patrons of journalism. “For the platforms, there are good reasons to deepen the relationship with news organizations. News are a free –and prominent– source of content and engagement on digital platforms” (Nechushtai, 2018Nechushtai, E. (2018). Could digital platforms capture the media through infrastructure? Journalism, 19(8), 1043–1058. DOI: 10.1177/1464884917725163
https://doi.org/10.1177/1464884917725163...
, p.1049). At the same time, these projects focus on journalism that follows the logic of the technology companies, meaning they subordinate the innovation of journalism to their own parameters rather than the parameters of journalism. According to the Reuters Institute, “publishers do not want hand-outs from platforms but would prefer a level playing field where they can compete fairly and get proper compensation for the value their content brings” (Newman, 2020Newman, N., Fletcher, R., Schulz, A., Andı, A., & Nielsen, R. (2020) Digital News Report 2020. Oxford: Reuters Institute. Retrieved from www.digitalnewsreport.org/
www.digitalnewsreport.org/...
, p.15).

The hope that Silicon Valley will save journalism is fading away: “If news outlets were once cautiously optimistic about what their relationships with platforms might yield, that has now turned to seasoned skepticism” (Tow Center for Digital Journalism, 2018Tow Center for Digital Journalism. (2018). Friend & Foe: The Platform Press at the Heart of Journalism. New York, Columbia Journalism School., p.25). News organizations have realized the magnitude of the power Facebook and Google have over the news industry, hence why some news organizations are establishing a more cautious relationship with these companies9 9 For several years there has been a debate about whether Facebook and Google should finance journalism, not through philanthropic projects but through taxes established by competition regulatory bodies. Some of the countries that have pushed through with these proposals are France, Australia, Canada, and United Kingdom. See: Flew, T., & Wilding D. (2020). The turn to regulation in digital communication: the ACCC’s digital platforms inquiry and Australian media policy. Media, Culture & Society, 1–18. DOI: 10.1177/0163443720926044 .

Some authors argue that the platforms do not benefit from the content of the news organizations. They instead offer traffic and audiences. The problems lie in the fact that news organizations have not taken advantage of that situation10 10 Jeff Jarvis from the University of New York is one of the staunch defenders of the idea that Facebook and Google are complementary to the work of journalism, See: “Jeff Jarvis: Stop being jealous and start solving problems”. Retrieved from https://blog.wan-ifra.org/2016/03/29/jeff-jarvis-stop-being-jealous-and-start-solving-problems . That is why this debate has to take different points of view and theoretical possibilities into account. The situation needs to be analyzed structurally. Technological convergence requires epistemological convergence; therefore, the attention economy offers a new perspective from which to view the crisis journalism is going through. As mentioned at the start, there are many causes and consequences to this crisis.

There is no single crisis of journalism; it is an industry that faces several crises on several fronts. But what is clear is that the crises require analysis and answers, this is why journalists and researchers must recognize the influence of Facebook and Google in the news industry and identify when they can act as allies and when they become competitors.

7 Conclusions

In the digital world, news organizations have to recognize that other news outlets are not their only competition; rather, their big competitors are Facebook and Google. The fact that other news organizations are competing for users’ attention and advertising revenue is not what makes today’s journalism unsustainable. The problem is that two big tech companies have acquired an unprecedented strength in capturing and selling attention.

The companies from Silicon Valley have indeed affected the news industry, but part of the responsibility lies with the news organizations who blindly believed their promises. They trusted their sustainability and business models to the algorithms designed and controlled by the platforms. Too late they discovered that the companies that promised them more reach, views, and the audience also competed with them for advertising revenue.

What can news organizations do about the dominance that Facebook and Google have in the attention market? Journalism is still an essential part of public opinion and democracy, so organizations have to establish sources of revenue that guarantee them autonomy in content production, distribution, and usage.

International studies show how some news organizations have adapted to the new conditions in the digital world (Jenkins, 2020Jenkis, J. (2020). Publish Less, but Publish Better: Pivoting to Paid in Local News. Oxford: Reuters Institute.; Newman et al., 2020Newman N. (2020). Journalism, Media, and Technology Trends and Predictions 2020. Oxford: Reuters Institute for the Study of Journalism.). These strategies indicate there is no single solution that can be replicated in each situation. Every news organization needs to explore ways of generating revenue without losing its role in society and becoming subordinate to the algorithms of Google, Facebook, or any other intermediary.

Many media outlets jump onto current trends without thinking critically: Facebook lives, Twitter threads, Instagram Stories, TikTok videos. Is it possible to monetize the use of these platforms? Which platform generates more revenue? Is monetization through platforms part of a sustainability strategy? Who benefits from producing news under the parameters of the tech companies? These are some questions that news organizations need to resolve before signing up for the latest technology.

While it has become clear that digital and analog publicity are not comparable (Tow Center for Digital Journalism, 2018Tow Center for Digital Journalism. (2018). Friend & Foe: The Platform Press at the Heart of Journalism. New York, Columbia Journalism School.), some organizations continue to go for easy clicks and traffic at any cost; for them, it might be the only way to survive. Others might revert to subscriptions, memberships, and donations as options to directly generate revenue from their audiences. Their success depends on factors like credibility, quality, and the readership they are aiming at11 11 An important point that must be explored in greater depth is the role states have to take with their regulatory bodies. The power and the monopoly that some North American tech companies have acquired invites a review of the regulatory frameworks and the conditions under which they compete in international and regional markets, affecting the industry, work, privacy, and sovereignty. . What is true is that sources of revenue and the business model both affect the type of journalism that is produced.

To conclude, each news organization needs to find out what is most beneficial for its circumstances. It is very probable that what works for The New York Times or The Guardian, is not the answer for a small local or regional news organization from a middle-sized city or a middle-income country.

Although news organizations and digital platforms are part of the same market, their goals, purposes, and audience commitments are different. What is fundamental for news organizations in the current market is to take back control and autonomy over their content and audiences. News organizations should not put their hopes and future in the hands of strategies developed by the Silicon Valley tech companies. Only quality journalism that is true to its socials purposes can guarantee sustainability in the news industry.

NOTES

  • 1
    The presented reflections are part of the project “The crisis of journalism: challenges and opportunities for the profession and the information industry in the digital era (Phase I)”, financed by the School of Human Sciences and the Research and Innovation Directorate of the Universidad del Rosario, Bogotá, Colombia.
  • 2
    On a global level, Google and Facebook hold 55% of the advertising revenue. See: Statista. (2019). Digital Economy compass. Retrieved from www.statista.com/study/52194/digital-economy-compass/
  • 3
    Part of the hope was that alternative digital media that would transform the news industry. Buzzfeed, a digital media outlet from the United States founded by Jonah Peretti exemplified the way that this new type of journalism could use technology to reach bigger audiences. In 2014, Peretti announced a new golden age for news organizations and journalism. Retrieved from https://medium.com/@peretti/is-history-repeating-itself-33390aeb6cd9
  • 4
    There are researchers that state that the advertising model from Facebook and Google stimulates the production and circulation of fake news, because it enables websites with false information to monetize their content. See: Braun, J., & Eklund J. (2019). Fake News, Real Money: Ad Tech Platforms, Profit-Driven Hoaxes, and the Business of Journalism. Digital Journalism, 7(1), 1–21.
  • 5
    One of the strategies that has been adopted by some journalism companies to attract visitors is what is known as “clickbait”, which consists of creating eye-catching headlines for users to click and access the content.
  • 6
    In 2018, Facebook announced a change in its algorithm to prioritize users over content from journalism companies. This decision generated ire from some news organizations who had adapted their strategies to the existing algorithms, so this modification changed the visibility of journalism products. See: “Facebook drastically changes News Feed to make it ‘good for people’ (and bad for most publishers)” Retrieved from www.niemanlab.org/2018/01/facebook-drastically-changes-news-feed-to-make-it-good-for-people-and-bad-for-most-publishers/?relatedstory Some news organizations opted to not publish their content on this social network. See: “Folha deixa de publicar conteúdo no Facebook”. Retrieved from www1.folha.uol.com.br/poder/2018/02/folha-deixa-de-publicar-conteudo-no-facebook.shtml
  • 7
    Due to the fall in advertising revenue, many news organizations are exploring new business models to diversify their revenue sources, including subscriptions, donations, events, education, and training programs. See: Jenkins, J. (2020). Publish less, but publish better: pivoting to paid in local news. Oxford: Reuters Institute. See: Tejedor, S., Ventín, A., Cervi, L., Pulido, C., & Tusa, F. (2020). Native Media and Business Models: Comparative Study of 14 Successful Experiences in LatinAmerica. Media and Communication, 8(2), 146–158. DOI:10.17645/mac.v8i2.2712
  • 8
    An article from Smythe generated an exchange of ideas that became known as “the blindspot debate”. See: Livant, B. (1978). The Audience Commodity: On the “Blindspot Debate”. CTheory, 3(1), 91–106. See: Murdock, G. (1978). Blindspots about western Marxism: A reply to Dallas Smythe. CTheory, 2(2), 109–115. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13744. See: Smythe, D. (1978) Rejoinder to Graham Murdock. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 2(2), 120–127. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13745
  • 9
    For several years there has been a debate about whether Facebook and Google should finance journalism, not through philanthropic projects but through taxes established by competition regulatory bodies. Some of the countries that have pushed through with these proposals are France, Australia, Canada, and United Kingdom. See: Flew, T., & Wilding D. (2020). The turn to regulation in digital communication: the ACCC’s digital platforms inquiry and Australian media policy. Media, Culture & Society, 1–18. DOI: 10.1177/0163443720926044
  • 10
    Jeff Jarvis from the University of New York is one of the staunch defenders of the idea that Facebook and Google are complementary to the work of journalism, See: “Jeff Jarvis: Stop being jealous and start solving problems”. Retrieved from https://blog.wan-ifra.org/2016/03/29/jeff-jarvis-stop-being-jealous-and-start-solving-problems
  • 11
    An important point that must be explored in greater depth is the role states have to take with their regulatory bodies. The power and the monopoly that some North American tech companies have acquired invites a review of the regulatory frameworks and the conditions under which they compete in international and regional markets, affecting the industry, work, privacy, and sovereignty.
  • TRANSLATED BY: Freek Huigen

REFERENCES

  • Anderson, C. (2020). The State(s) of Things. 20 Years of Journalism Studies and Political Communication. Comunicazione política, 21(1), 47-62. DOI: 10.3270/96422
    » https://doi.org/10.3270/96422
  • Bell, E., & Owen, T. (2017). The platform press. How Silicon Valley reengineered journalism New York: Columbia Journalism School.
  • Bermejo, F. (2009). Audience manufacture in historical perspective: from broadcasting to Google. New Media & Society, 11(1–2), 133–154. DOI: 10.1177/1461444808099579
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444808099579
  • Bolaño, C., & Vieira, E. (2014). Economía política da internet e os sites de redes sociais, Revista Eptic, 16(2), 71– 84. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/2168
    » https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/2168
  • Bucher, T. (2012). A technicity of attention: how software ‘makes sense’. Culture Machine, 13, 1–23. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
    » www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
  • Cagé, J. (2016). Salvar los medios de comunicación Barcelona, Anagrama.
  • Crogan, P., & Kinsley S. (2012). Paying attention: towards a critique of the attention economy. Culture Machine, 13, 1–29. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
    » www.culturemachine.net/paying-attention/
  • Dantas, M., & Raulino, G. (2020). Trabalho da audiência e renda informacional no Facebook e no YouTube. Revista Eptic, 22(1), 123–141. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12215
    » https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12215
  • Dijck, J. van, Poell, T., & Waal, M. (2018). The platform society: Public values in a connective world New York, Oxford University Press.
  • Galloway, S. (2018). Four. El ADN secreto de Amazon, Apple, Facebook y Google Barcelona: Penguin Random House.
  • Gillespie, T. (2010). The politics of ‘platforms’. New Media & Society, 12(3), 347–364. DOI: 10.1177/1461444809342738
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444809342738
  • Gillespie, T. (2018). Custodians of the internet. Platforms, content moderation, and the hidden decisions that shape social media New Haven: Yale University Press.
  • Goldhaber, M. (1997). The Attention Economy on the Net. First Monday, 2(4). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
    » https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v2i4.519
  • Goldhaber, M. (2006). The value of openness in an attention economy. First Monday, 11(6). DOI: 10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334
    » https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v11i6.1334
  • Jarvis, J. (2015). El fin de los medios de comunicación de masa México: Paidós.
  • Jenkis, J. (2020). Publish Less, but Publish Better: Pivoting to Paid in Local News Oxford: Reuters Institute.
  • Ju, A., Jeong, S., & Chyi, I. (2014). Will social media save newspapers? Examining the effectiveness of Facebook and Twitter as news platform. Journalism Practice, 8(1), 1–17. DOI: 10.1080/17512786.2013.794022
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/17512786.2013.794022
  • Jurno, A., & D’Andréa, C. (2020). Facebook e a plataformização do jornalismo: um olhar para os Instant Articles. Revista Eptic, 22(1), 179–196. Retrieved from https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12084
    » https://seer.ufs.br/index.php/eptic/article/view/12084
  • Kessous, E., Mellet, K., & Zouinar, M. (2010). L’Économie de l’attention: entre protection des ressources cognitives et extraction de la valeur. Sociologie du Travail, 52(3), 359–373. DOI: 10.4000/sdt.14802
    » https://doi.org/10.4000/sdt.14802
  • Fuchs, C. (2012). Dallas Smythe Today-The Audience Commodity, the Digital Labour Debate, Marxist Political Economy and Critical Theory. TripleC, 10(2), 692–740. DOI: 10.31269/triplec.v10i2.443
    » https://doi.org/10.31269/triplec.v10i2.443
  • Lanham, R. (2006). The economics of attention. Style and substance in the age of information Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
  • Lee, M. (2011). Google ads and the blindspot debate. Media, Culture & Society, 33(3), 433–447. DOI: 10.1177/0163443710394902
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0163443710394902
  • Marín, B. (2019). La tiranía del clic Madrid: Turner.
  • Myllylahti, M. (2018) An attention economy trap? An empirical investigation into four news companies’ Facebook traffic and social media revenue. Journal of Media Business Studies, 15(4), 237–253. DOI: 10.1080/16522354.2018.1527521
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/16522354.2018.1527521
  • Myllylahti, M. (2020). Paying Attention to Attention: A Conceptual Framework for Studying News Reader Revenue Models Related to Platforms. Digital Journalism, 8(5), 567–575. DOI: 10.1080/21670811.2019.1691926
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/21670811.2019.1691926
  • Napoli, P., & Caplan, R. (2019). Por qué las empresas de medios insisten en que no son empresas de medios, por qué están equivocadas y por qué es importante. Hipertextos, 12(7), 15–46. DOI: 10.24215/23143924e002
    » https://doi.org/10.24215/23143924e002
  • Nechushtai, E. (2018). Could digital platforms capture the media through infrastructure? Journalism, 19(8), 1043–1058. DOI: 10.1177/1464884917725163
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1464884917725163
  • Newman, N., Fletcher, R., Kalogeropoulos, A., & Nielsen, R. (2019) Digital News Report 2019 Oxford: Reuters Institute. Retrieved from www.digitalnewsreport.org/
    » www.digitalnewsreport.org/
  • Newman, N., Fletcher, R., Schulz, A., Andı, A., & Nielsen, R. (2020) Digital News Report 2020 Oxford: Reuters Institute. Retrieved from www.digitalnewsreport.org/
    » www.digitalnewsreport.org/
  • Newman N. (2020). Journalism, Media, and Technology Trends and Predictions 2020 Oxford: Reuters Institute for the Study of Journalism.
  • Nieborg, D., & Poell, T. (2018). The platformization of cultural production: Theorizing the contingent cultural commodity. New Media & Society, 20(11), 4275–4292. DOI: 10.1177/1461444818769694
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444818769694
  • Nielsen, R. (2020). Building the Business We Want. In N. Newman (Ed.), Journalism, Media, and Technology Trends and Predictions 2020 (pp.26–27). Oxford: Reuters Institute for the Study of Journalism.
  • Nielsen, R., & Ganter, S. (2018). Dealing with digital intermediaries: A case study of the relations between publishers and platforms. New Media & Society, 20(4), 1600–1617. DOI: 10.1177/1461444817701318
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1461444817701318
  • Nixon, B. (2017). Critical Communication Policy Research and the Attention Economy: From Digital Labor Theory to Digital Class Struggle. International Journal of Communication, 11, 4718–4730. Retrieved from www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view/7005
    » www.ijoc.org/index.php/ijoc/article/view/7005
  • Pariser, E. (2017). El filtro burbuja. Cómo la red decide lo que leemos y lo que pensamos Barcelona: Taurus.
  • Ramonet, I. (2012). La explosión del periodismo. Internet pone en jaque a los medios tradicionales Bogotá: Le Monde diplomatic.
  • Rasmusen, E. (2007). Games and information. An Introduction to Game Theory Victoria: Blackwell Publishing.
  • Salazar, D. (2019). No hemos entendido nada Barcelona: Debate.
  • Siapera, E. (2013). Platform infomediation and journalism. Culture Machine, 14, 1–28. Retrieved from www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics/
    » www.culturemachine.net/platform-politics/
  • Simon, H. (1971) Designing Organizations for an Information Rich World. In M. Greenberger (Ed.), Computers, Communication, and the Public Interest (pp.37–72). Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.
  • Smythe, D. (1977). Communications: blindspot of western marxism. Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory, 1(3), 1–27. Retrieved from https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
    » https://journals.uvic.ca/index.php/ctheory/article/view/13715
  • Smythe, D. (2006). On the audience commodity and its work. In M. Durham & D. Kellner (Eds.), Media and cultural studies – Keyworks (pp.230–256). Malden: Blackwell.
  • Srnicek, N. (2018). Capitalismo de plataformas Buenos Aires: Caja Negra.
  • Tow Center for Digital Journalism. (2018). Friend & Foe: The Platform Press at the Heart of Journalism New York, Columbia Journalism School.
  • Thompson, D. (2018). Creadores de hits. La ciencia de la popularidad en la era de la distracción México, Océano.
  • Webster, J. (2014). The marketplace of attention. How audiences take shape in a digital age Cambridge: MIT Press
  • Wu, T. (2017). The attention Merchants. New York: Knopf.
  • Zelizer, B. (2015). Terms of Choice: Uncertainty, Journalism, and Crisis. Journal of Communication, 65(5), 888–908. DOI: 10.1111/jcom.12157
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/jcom.12157

Edited by

Desk Review Editor: Tania Rosas-Moreno

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    15 Apr 2022
  • Date of issue
    Jan-Apr 2021

History

  • Received
    13 July 2020
  • Reviewed
    09 Aug 2020
  • Reviewed
    22 Sept 2020
  • Reviewed
    16 Nov 2020
  • Accepted
    15 Dec 2020
Associação Brasileira de Pesquisadores em Jornalismo (SBPJor) Secretaria da SBPJor, Faculdade de Comunicação, Universidade de Brasília(UnB)., ICC Norte, Subsolo, Sala ASS 633 - cep: 70910-900, Brasília - DF / Brasil - Brasília - DF - Brazil
E-mail: sbpjor.dir.adm@gmail.com