Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Green economy and green jobs: a multisectoral analysis by means of Spain’s social accounting matrix

Economia verde e empregos verdes: uma análise multissetorial por meio da matriz de contabilidade social da Espanha

ABSTRACT

During the last decades the green economy has been proposed from different international organizations as an economic model for the 21st century that gravitates around respecting the environment. This paper tries to identify, with criteria of economic efficiency (high economic impact) and social efficiency (high impact on job creation, green jobs), the “potentially green sectors” that can be stimulated by a national strategy to develop a green economy in Spain. For this, we will use the Social Accounting Matrix of Spain 2010, identifying, by means of the normalized absorption and diffusion coefficients and by means of employment multipliers, the key, drivers and with greater capacity for job creation sectors from a group of ten sectors that we have identified as “potentially green sectors”.

KEYWORDS:
Green economy; green jobs; SAM model; Spanish economy; economic policy

RESUMO

Durante as últimas décadas a economia verde tem sido proposta por diversos organismos internacionais como um modelo econômico para o século XXI que gravita em torno do respeito ao meio ambiente. Este artigo tenta identificar, com critérios de eficiência econômica (alto impacto econômico) e eficiência social (alto impacto na geração de empregos, empregos verdes), os “setores potencialmente verdes” que podem ser estimulados por uma estratégia nacional para desenvolver uma economia verde na Espanha. Para isso, utilizaremos a Matriz de Contabilidade Social da Espanha 2010, identificando, por meio dos coeficientes de absorção e difusão normalizados e por meio de multiplicadores de emprego, os setores-chave, impulsionadores e com maior capacidade de criação de emprego de um grupo de dez setores que identificamos como “setores potencialmente verdes”.

PALAVRAS-CHAVE:
Economia verde; empregos verdes; modelo SAM; economia espanhola; política econômica

1. INTRODUCTION

The links between economy and nature were never a main concern to the economists, except in the early stages of Economy as a science, with the works of the French physiocrats such as Tableau Économique (Quesnay, 1758Quesnay, F. (1758). Tableau Economique, London: British Economic Association.), and with the work An Essay on the Principle of Population (Malthus, 1798Malthus, T.R. (1798). An Essay on the Principle of Population, London: Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project.). It wasn’t until the 1970s that the relationship gained prominence once again in this field, with The Limits to Growth (Meadows et al., 1972Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., Randers, J., Behrens, W. (1972). The Limits to Growth, Washington, D.C.: Potomac Associates.). This document started what we could call the “pessimistic” trend of the relationships between economy and nature, founded under the principle that there are biophysical limits to growth. Opposing this relationship, soon would their antithesis arise, the “optimistic” trend of the relationships between economy and nature. Its first main exponents were the compilation of essays from The Resourceful Earth (Simon and Kahn, 1984Simon, J.L., Kahn, H. (1984). The Resourceful Earth: A Response to Global 2000, New York: Basil Blackwell.), under the idea that both the market and technology would allow to easily solve the conflicts among economy and nature. Furthermore, as a synthesis of both currents, the “possibilist” trend would also arise. It is based on the idea that it is possible to implement an economic model which will make the economic growth compatible with the sufficient preservation of nature, in order to allow proper living standards in the future. The document referring to this “possibility” trend was Our Common Future (World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987World Commission on Environment and Development. (1987). Our Common Future, Oxford: Oxford University Press.), from which the expression sustainable development became popular. It is within this framework of “possibilist” trend, based on the idea of a sustainable development that we must subscribe to the proposal of a green economy. Matches with UNEP (2011UNEP. (2011). Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication, Nairobi: United Nations Environment Program.) that defines green economy as enhancing natural capital - that is, stocks of and flows from crops, fisheries, water bodies and forests - and energy and resource efficiency -that is, enabling environmental technology in renewable energy, manufacturing, waste management, buildings, transport, tourism, and cities.

The concept of green economy, coined by Pearce et al. (1989Pearce, D., Markandya, A., Barbier, E. (1989). Blueprint for Green Economy, New York: Earthscan. url: https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203097298
https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203097298...
), became popular upon the proposal of the General Assembly of the United Nations to organize a Conference on Sustainable Development in 2012, in Rio de Janeiro (Brazil). Green economy is an economic model which focuses on improving the welfare of human beings and social equality, reducing carbon emissions, increasing earnings, creating jobs, promoting energy efficiency, and using resources and halting the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services (Herrán, 2012Herrán, C. (2012). El camino hacia una economía verde, México, D.F.: Proyecto Energía y Clima de la Fundación Friedrich Ebert.: 2). In this sense, the green economy would be an umbrella concept that would include both the bioeconomy and the circular economy (D’Amato et al., 2017D’Amato, D., Droste, N., Allen, B., Kettunen, M., Lähtinen, K., Korhonen, J., Leskinen, P., Matthies, B.D., Toppinen, A. (2017). “Green, Circular, Bio-economy: A comparative analysis of three sustainability avenues”. Journal Cleaner Production, 168, 716-734. url: https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053
https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053...
: 726; Pearce and Turner, 1990Pearce, D., Turner, R. K. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.). This understanding allows the inclusion of green economy within the scope of sustainable development and the eradication of poverty, highlighting its economic, social, and environmental dimensions (Mahnkopf, 2014Mahnkopf, B. (2014). “Desigualdad social o giro a economía verde: respuesta adecuada para la crisis época del capitalismo”. Revista Mundo Siglo XXI, 34. url: https://repositorio.flacsoandes.edu.ec/xmlui/handle/10469/7039
https://repositorio.flacsoandes.edu.ec/x...
: 34-35). Therefore, it could be considered as a proposal for sustainable development in the form of weak sustainability, specific to environmental economy. Moreover, as far as the European Union is concerned, green economy is part of the strategy Europe 2020 (European Commission, 2010European Commission. (2010). Europe 2020: A Strategy for Smart, Sustainable and Inclusive Growth. COM(2010) 2020 final, Brussels. url: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/...
), and its reaffirmation into A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low Carbon Economy in 2050 (European Commission, 2011European Commission. (2011). A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low Carbon Economy in 2050. COM(2011) 112 final, Brussels. url: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2009_2014/documents/com/com_com(2011)0112_/com_com(2011)0112_en.pdf
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/...
) and The European Green Deal (European Commission, 2019European Commission. (2019). The European Green Deal. COM(2019) 640 final. url: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/...
), where the aim is to achieve a low-carbon economy. As noted by the European Union, the concept of green economy could be understood as a response to the various financial, environmental, climate and social crises that have occurred worldwide leading to question the strength of the traditional economic growth models and the role they play in the development or worsening of such crises, emphasizing that technological advances are the key for a sustainable economic growth (European Network for Rural Development, 2017European Network for Rural Development. (2017). “Transition to the green economy”. EU Rural Review, 23, 4-8.: 5).

Related to the green economy concept we came across the concept of green jobs. This concept is defined as the work activity that helps to protect the environment and fights against climate change, by saving energy and commodities, promoting renewable energy, reducing waste and contamination, and protecting biodiversity and ecosystems. In addition, it involves adequate earnings, acceptable working conditions, appropriate social protection, respecting the rights of workers and their involvement in decisions that will ultimately affect their lives (Jiménez Herrero and Leiva, 2010Jiménez Herrero, L.M., Leiva, A., (2010). Informe empleo verde en una economía sostenible, Madrid: Observatorio de la Sostenibilidad de España y Fundación Biodiversidad.: 6).

During the last decade, research studies on the green economy labor market have multiplied and yielded mixed results. Some studies consider that environmental regulation hampers competitiveness because it offers low profitability and is detrimental to job creation. For example, in the case of the United Kingdom, in order to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by 34% they must sacrifice at least 5% of their GDP, consequently impacting employment because of the elimination of jobs in the affected sectors would not be compensated with the creation of jobs in the sectors benefited from the environmental regulation (Hughes, 2011Hughes, G. (2011). The Myth of Green Jobs, London: The Global Warming Policy Foundation.: 36-37). In the same vein, other authors (Dechezleprêtre and Sato, 2014Dechezleprêtre, A., Sato, M. (2014). The Impacts of Environmental Regulations on Competitiveness. Policy Brief, London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment and The London School of Economics.: 18-19) claim that although the change towards a more sustainable economy generates new jobs, these jobs are fewer than the jobs that have been eliminated. There are also studies claiming that a higher environmental regulation shall lead to companies’ off-shoring production to territories with looser environmental legislations, thereby eliminating employment in those countries with higher regulations (Mulatu and Wossink, 2014Mulatu, A., Wossink, A. (2014). “Environmental Regulation and Location of Industrialized Agricultural Production in Europe”. Land Economics, 90, (3), 509-537.: 527; Kahn and Mansur, 2013Kahn, M.E., Mansur, E.T. (2013). “Do local energy prices and regulation affect the geographic concentration of employment?” Journal Public Economics, 101(C), 105-114. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.03.002
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.0...
: 111-112). There is no lack of studies claiming the existence of myths related to green jobs, given the fact that most of the employment resulting from the environmental regulation activities will be non-productive bureaucratic jobs (Morris et al., 2009Morris, A.P., Bogart, W.T., Dorchak, A., Meiners, R.E. (2009). “Green Jobs Myths”. Case Legal Studies Research Paper, 09-15. Illinois Law & Economics Research Paper No. LE09-001. url: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1358423
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1358423...
: 95-97).

However, other groups defend the positive effects of the environmental regulation policies on employment. Thus, some studies argue that investing in renewable energies creates more jobs per units of energy produced than investing in energies originating from fossil fuels (Wei et al., 2010Wei, M., Patadia, S., Kammen, D.M. (2010). “Putting renewable and energy efficiency to work: how many jobs can the clean energy industry generate in the US?” Energy Policy, 38, (2), 919-932. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.10.044
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.10....
: 928-930). Other studies based on the circular economy theory have reached similar conclusions (Loiseau et al., 2013Loiseau, E., Saikku, L., Antikainen, R., Droste, N., Hansjürgens-Pitkanen, K., Leskinen, P., Kuikman, P., Thomsen, M. (2016). “Green economy and related concepts”. Journal Cleaner Production, 139, 361-371. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.024
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.0...
; D’Amato et al., 2017D’Amato, D., Droste, N., Allen, B., Kettunen, M., Lähtinen, K., Korhonen, J., Leskinen, P., Matthies, B.D., Toppinen, A. (2017). “Green, Circular, Bio-economy: A comparative analysis of three sustainability avenues”. Journal Cleaner Production, 168, 716-734. url: https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053
https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053...
). There are also studies by countries showing that the environmental policies driven by governments have generated positive employment effects, as it has occurred in China (Cai, 2011Cai, W., Wang, C., Chen, J., Wang, S. (2011). “Green economy and green jobs: myth or reality? The case of China’s power generation sector”. Energy, 36, (10), 5994-6003. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2011.08.016
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2011.08...
: 5999-6001), Brazil (Borges and Montibeler, 2014Borges, R., Montibeler E.E. (2014). “Input-Output Matrix study: A theoretical frame to study the impact of Brazilian IPI reduction in final demand”. EconomiA 15, 2, 228-241.) and the United States (Yi, 2013Yi, H. (2013). “Clean energy policies and green jobs: an evaluation of green jobs in US metropolitan areas”. Energy Policy, 56, 644-652. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.034
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01....
: 651-652). In other cases, we have encountered studies on regional economies claiming that regional public policies enable the restructure of economy to improve environmental sustainability and has substantial positive outcomes in terms of job creation (Connolly et al., 2016Connolly, K., Allan, G.J., McIntyre, S.G. (2016). “The evolution of green jobs in Scotland: a hybrid approach”. Energy Policy, 88, 355-360. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.10.044
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.10....
: 358-359; Battaglia et al., 2018Battaglia, M., Cerrini, E., Annesi, N. (2018). “Can environmental agreements represent an opportunity for green jobs? Evidence from two Italian experiences”. Journal of Clearner Production, 175, 257-266. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.12.086
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.1...
: 264-265; Unay-Gailharda and Bojnecb, 2019Unay-Gailharda, I., Bojnecb, S. (2019). “The impact of green economy measures on rural employment: Green jobs in farms”. Journal of Cleaner Production, 208, 541-551. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.10.160
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.1...
: 544-547). Other research studies include that environmental regulation must be accompanied by investment in human capital and innovation in order for the creation of green jobs to surpass the elimination of conventional jobs (Cesere and Mazzanti, 2017Cesere, G., Mazzanti, M. (2017). “Green jobs and eco-innovations in European SMEs”. Resource and Energy Economics, 49, 86-98. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.03.003
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017...
: 88-92; Consoli et al., 2016Consoli, D., Marin, G., Marzucchi, A., Vona, F. (2016). “Do green jobs differ from non-green jobs in terms of skills and human capital?” Research Policy, 45, (5), 1046-1060. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.02.007
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.02...
: 1055-1056; Chenoweth et al., 2018Chenoweth, J., Anderson, A.R., Kumar, P., Hunt, W.F., Chimbwandira, S.J., Moore, T. L. (2018). “The interrelationship of green infrastructure and natural capital”. Land Use Policy, 75, 137-144. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.03.021
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.201...
: 142-143), this last approach is included within the scope of green economic development, focused on promoting investment in research and human capital formation in order to develop a productive sustainable model (Hess et al., 2018Hess, D.J., Quan, D.M., Skaggs, R., Sudibjo, M. (2018). “Local matters: Political opportunities, spatial scale, and support for green jobs policies”. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 26, 158-170. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eist.2017.03.003
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eist.2017.03.0...
: 4). Nevertheless, green economic development could be considered as a variant of sustainable development in the form of environmental economics.

Considering the information states thus far, this study seeks to identify the green economy sectors which stimulus would generate a greater economic impact and a greater social impact (capacity to create green jobs) in the case of Spain. However, considering that the sectors that arise from the International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities (ISIC) are used in the elaboration of the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM), it is not possible to determine which specific activities of a certain sector or subsector really respond to a logical green economy and which ones are not. In practice, we can only make a sectoral approach to the green economy by identifying those sectors that have “potential” to really be green economy sectors under certain conditions (improving the welfare of human beings and social equality, reducing carbon emissions, increasing earnings, creating jobs, promoting energy efficiency, and using resources and halting the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services). These “potentially green sectors” would be those related to the bioeconomy and taken into consideration in the preparation of the bio-SAM of Spain as bio-based sector (Mainar et al., 2017aMainar, A.J., Fuentes, P.D., Ferrari, E. (2017a). “The role of bioeconomy sectors and natural resources in EU economies: A social accounting matrix-based analysis approach”. Sustainability, 9, (12), 1-13.)1 1 The available data does not allow a disaggregated classification of the bioeconomic sectors and neither of the circular economy sectors of the Spanish economy through its SAM; however, we have an approximation to the green economy in Spain thanks to the Spanish bio-SAM prepared by Mainar et al. (2017a). : crops2 2 Cereals (paddy rice, wheat, barley, maize, other cereals); vegetables (tomatoes, potatoes, other vegetables); fruits (grapes, other fruits); oilseeds (rape, sunflower, and soya seeds); oil plants (olives, other oil plants); industrial crops (sugar beet, fiber plants, tobacco); and other crops (live plants, other crops). , livestock3 3 Extensive livestock production (live bovine, sheep, goats, horses, asses, mules…); intensive livestock production (live swine, poultry); other live animals and animal products; raw milk. , fishing4 4 Fishing. , forestry5 5 Forestry, logging, and related service activities, energy crops include. , food industry6 6 Animal feed, fodder crops, biodiesel by-product oilcake; red meat (meat of bovine, meat of sheep, goats); white meat (meat of swine, poultry); vegetable oils; dairy; rice, processed; sugar, processed; olive oil; wine; beverages and tobacco; other food products). , wood industry7 7 Wood products, pellets include. , textile industry8 8 Textiles, wearing apparel and leather. , biochemical industry9 9 Biochemicals. , bioenergy industry10 10 Bioelectricity; biofuel 1st generation (bioethanol, biodiesel); biofuel 2nd generation (biochemical and thermal technology biofuel). . To these sectors we add the circular economy sector par excellence: water and waste11 11 Water distribution, sewerage, waste management and remediation activities. . We assume in the document that “potentially green sectors” are the best possible approximation to green economy sectors.

In this regard, we pose the following questions: What are the “potentially green sectors” which stimulus would generate a greater economic impact in Spain (driving areas and key sectors)? What are the “potentially green sectors” which stimulus would generate a greater social impact (“potentially green jobs”) in Spain?

Therefore, the goal of this study is to determine the “potentially green sectors” that could be considered as priority to be included by policy makers in an economic stimulus strategy based on their economic and social impact to visualize if the transition of the Spanish economy into the green economy would have a remarkable impact in economic growth and job creation. To determine the potential economic and social impact of promoting green economy we will perform a general equilibrium analysis based on the Spanish economy. We will use the Social Accounting Matrix of bioeconomy, or bio-SAM (Mainar et al., 2017aMainar, A.J., Fuentes, P.D., Ferrari, E. (2017a). “The role of bioeconomy sectors and natural resources in EU economies: A social accounting matrix-based analysis approach”. Sustainability, 9, (12), 1-13.), which introduces, in detail, the general equilibrium of an economy and captures the underlying connections within production, consumption and distribution (Mei-Mei et al., 2019Mei-Mei, X., Qiao-Mei, L., Wang, C. (2019). “Price transmission mechanism and socio-economic effect of carbon pricing in Beijing: A two-region social accounting matrix analysis”. Journal of Cleaner Production, 211, 134-145. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.116
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.1...
: 138). The Social Accounting Matrix has been widely used to study the relationships between economy and the environment to create national and regional policy recommendations (Hoekstra, 2010Hoekstra, R. (2010). A Complete Database of Peer-Reviewed Articles on Environmentally Extended Input-Output Analysis, Sydney: 18th International Input-Output Conference. url: https://www.iioa.org/conferences/18th/papers/files/36_20100614091_Hoekstra-EE-IOoverview-final.pdf
https://www.iioa.org/conferences/18th/pa...
; Chapa and Ortega, 2017Chapa, J., Ortega, A. (2017). “Carbon tax effects on the poor: A SAM-based approach”. Environmental Research Letters, 12, (9). url: http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa80ed
http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa80...
; Su and Ang, 2012Su, B., Ang, B.W. (2012). “Structural decomposition analysis applied to energy and emissions: Some methodological developments”. Energy Economics, 34, 177-188. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.10.009
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.10...
; Sato, 2014Sato, M. (2014). “Embodied carbon in trade: A survey of the empirical literature”. Journal of Economic Surveys, 28, 831-861. url: https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12027
https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12027...
; Campoy, 2017Campoy-Múñoz, P., Cardenete, M.A., Delgado, M.C. (2017). “Economic impact assessment of food waste reduction on European countries through social accounting matrices”. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 122, (202-209). url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2017.02.010
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2017...
; Fuentes et al., 2017Fuentes, P.D., Mainar, A.J. (2015). “Impacto económico y en el empleo de la Economía Social en España. Un análisis multisectorial”. Revista de Economía Pública, Social y Cooperativa, 83, 63-81.; Yingzhu et al., 2018Yingzhu, L., Bin, S., Dasgupta, S. (2018). “Structural path analysis of India’s carbon emissions using input-output and social accounting matrix frameworks”. Energy Economics, 76, 457-469. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.10.029
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.10....
).

2. MODEL ATTRIBUTES

The SAM model is an extension of the Input-Output table by Leontief (1936Leontief, W. (1936). “Quantitative Input-Output relations in the economic system of the United States”. Review of Economics and Statistics, 18, 105-125.: 105-125), developed by the Cambridge Growth Project (Stone, 1962Stone, R. (1962). A Social Accounting Matrix for 1960. A Program for Growth, London: Chapman and Hall.)12 12 A Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) represents the functioning of the economy of a territory for a prolonged period, in which its structure remains stable, and collects the monetary flows of the circuit of transactions among the different economic accounts (García-Remigio et al., 2020). To appreciate the existence of a structural change in an economy using social accounting matrices, it is necessary to resort to the comparison among the matrices of different periods of time (usually 10 years); however, structural change is not the object of study of this research. . A SAM offers in greater detail the income distribution structure, the taxation pattern and the existing transfer system in a country (Casares et al., 2017Casares, E.R., García-Salazar, M.G., Sobarzo, H. (2017). “Las Matrices de Contabilidad Social como base de datos y soporte de modelos multisectoriales”. EconoQuantum, 141, 119-142.: 120). In this sense, we find interesting cross-sectional analyzes by Soza and Ramos (2005Soza, S., Ramos, C. (2005). “Replanteamiento del análisis estructural a partir del análisis factorial. Una aplicación a las economías europeas”. Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 23, (2), 363-384.) based on economic sectors at a European level. The analysis was also done comparing Spanish regions, for example SAM from Andalusia against the SAM from Extremadura (Cardenete et al., 2000Cardenete, M.A., Congregado, E., De Miguel, F.J., Pérez, J. (2000). “Análisis comparativo de las economías andaluza y extremeña a través de sus MCS”. Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 15, 47-74.). SAM based analysis are considered to be a reliable tool for decision making with regards to economic policy by policy makers and to guide the measures to promote wealth and job creation.

In our case, we will use the bio-SAM Model for Spain, 2010 (Mainar et al., 2017aMainar, A.J., Fuentes, P.D., Ferrari, E. (2017a). “The role of bioeconomy sectors and natural resources in EU economies: A social accounting matrix-based analysis approach”. Sustainability, 9, (12), 1-13.) to identity the characteristics of the “potentially green sectors” and their capacity to generate indirect, direct, and total employment opportunities. The matrix used for this study is based on European research studies about the bio-SAM Model for European countries (Mainar et al., 2017bMainar, A.J., Philippidis, G., Sanjuan, A.I. (2017b). Analysis of Structural Patterns in Highly Disaggregated Bioeconomy Sectors by EU Member States Using SAM/IO Multipliers. EUR 28591. JRC Technical Reports. European Commission. Joint Research Centre. url: https://doi.org/10.2760/822918
https://doi.org/10.2760/822918...
).

2.1. Sector classification from a Social Accounting Matrix

SAM’s countable multipliers represent the full effect over each of their endogenous items from an additional unit impact within their set of exogenous variables. When these multipliers are applied to our research, they could be useful determining which of the so-called “potentially green sectors” is generating the biggest impact in economy and employment by the policy maker stimulus. To calculate these multipliers we must start from the following general expression (1) (Cardenete et al., 2015Cardenete, M.A., Fuentes, P., Mainar, A., Rodríguez, C. (2015). “Análisis y explotación mediante mode­los económicos multisectoriales de la Matriz de Contabilidad Social de Andalucía para 2008”. Regional and Sectorial Economic Studies, 15, (1), 153-168.: 154):

y n = A n y n + x = ( I - A ) - 1 x = M a x (1)

where yn is the column vector for the incomes of endogenous accounts, An is the matrix of the average propensity consumed by endogenous accounts. Their components (aij) represent the expenditure performed in the account i by each expenditure unit or usage unit of j, in which x is the column vector accounting for all the income flow received by the endogenous accounts from the exogenous accounts. Matrix Ma is the matrix of countable multipliers, the components (maij) represent the impact from an additional exogenous income unit on an endogenous account j, which is finally generated on the income of the endogenous account i.

The sum of the matrix column with countable multipliers (Ma) indicates the full effect from an exogenous shock received by an endogenous account for the economy as a whole. Thus, if the sum of a column from Ma had a very high value, it will indicate the account has a greater influence over the rest of the economy when receiving an exogenous shock (for example, a measure of economic policy). From Ma we can calculate the absorption and diffusion coefficients. Absorption coefficients are calculated by the sum of all the elements on each raw Ma (2):

M i . = j = 1 n m i j (2)

This column (Mi.) indicates the accounts absorbing most of the growth produced for the economy as a whole, because its value is reflected on the income of the account i when an exogenous income unit injection takes place in the economic system. Diffusion coefficients are calculated by the sum of all the elements on each column Ma (3):

M . j = i = 1 n m i j (3)

This raw (M.j) indicates the accounts with the highest expansion effect on income for the economy as a whole, because its value is reflected on the income of the total endogenous account when an increase on exogenous income unit occurs in the account j.

From Mi. y M.j we can calculate Rasmussen’s (1956Rasmussen, P. (1956). Studies in Intersectorial Relations, Amsterdam: North-Holland.) absorption and diffusion coefficients, which standardize the absorption and diffusion coefficients by linking them to global absorption and diffusion averages and providing a relative measure of the importance of such effects.

Rasmussen’s absorption coefficient, or dispersion responsiveness, (Ui.) would be (4):

F L : U i . = 1 n j = 1 n m i j 1 n 2 j = 1 n j = 1 n m i j = M i . 1 n j = 1 n j = 1 n m i j (4)

and it would represent the absorptive capacity (dispersion responsiveness), in relative terms, from each account receiving an increased income, or their forward linkages (FL). While Rasmussen’s diffusion coefficient, or power of dispersion, (U.j) would be (5):

B L : U . j = 1 n i = 1 n m i j 1 n 2 j = 1 n i = 1 n m i j = M . j 1 n j = 1 n i = 1 n m i j (5)

and it would represent the diffusing force (power of diffusion), in relative terms, from each account receiving an increased income, or their backward linkages (BL).

This way we can affirm that a sector presents strong forward linkages (FL), if products are obtained from their business activities that will be used in other branches during their production process (absorption or forward expansion); while a sector presents strong backward linkages (BL) if it insists on input from the rest, inducing the development of other activities (López Álvarez, 2015López Álvarez, J.M. (2015). Análisis del cambio estructural de la economía andaluza a través de instrumentos de modelización multisectorial [PhD Dissertation], Pablo de Olavide University, Seville (Spain).: 12-1). Taking into consideration the forward linkage (FL) and the backward linkage (BL) from each sector we can classify the economic sectors (Table 1).

Table 1
Economic sector classification according to their relationships with other sectors

Thus, if the diffusion effect from the sector (FL) is below the median of the diffusion effect for the economy as a whole (U.j<1) and the absorption effect of that sector (BL) is also below the median of the absorption effect for the economy as a whole (Ui.<1), it would be treated as an independent sector, island sector or other sector (with very few links to other national sectors). It is common for an independent sector to present substantial backward and forward linkages with the external sector. They tend to have a strong quantitative importance in enclave economies; the textile industry is a good example for those countries where maquiladoras textile enterprises prevail.

If the diffusion effect from the sector (FL) is below the median of the diffusion effect for the economy as a whole (U.j<1) and the absorption effect of that sector (BL) is above the median of the absorption effect for the economy as a whole (Ui.>1), it would be treated as a base sector or strategic sector (with substantial links to clients from domestic sectors). The importance of a base sector lies in its capacity to bottleneck the economy, that is, a relative shortage in production or weak growth of a base sector could end up paralyzing other sectors or curbing their expansion. A good example would be the mining industry in areas with highly developed industries dedicated to processing mineral products.

If the diffusion effect from the sector (FL) is above the median of the diffusion effect for the economy as a whole (U.j>1) and the absorption effect of that sector (BL) is below the median of the absorption effect for the economy as a whole (Ui.<1), it will be treated as a driving sector or motor sector (with substantial links to their supplying sectors). The importance of a driving sector lies in its capacity to spillover to the supplying sectors, that is, the expansion of a sector will consequently stimulate the production of their supplying sectors and a recession in a driving sector will anticipate a posterior recession in many other sectors. A good example is the construction sector, especially if it is primarily nourished by domestic products.

While if the diffusion effect from the sector (FL) is above the median of the diffusion effect for the economy as a whole (U.j>1) and the absorption effect of that sector (BL) is also above the median of the absorption effect for the economy as a whole (Ui.>1), it would be treated as a key sector (with substantial sectoral backwards linkages, domestic suppliers, and forward, with domestic clients). The importance of a key sector lies in its double role as a base sector and driving sector, that is, its simultaneous capacity to bottleneck and simultaneous capacity to spillover. A good example of a key sector is the iron and steel industry, when there is both an important domestic metallic mining sector, as well as an important domestic sector of metallurgical industry.

2.2. Employment multipliers from a Social Accounting Matrix

The employment multipliers of a SAM model provide information about the expansionary impact that final demand shocks have on domestic usage; that is, they show us each sector’s responsiveness rate, in terms of employment, to the changes in the demand. This multiplier originates from Pasinetti’s (1973Pasinetti, L. (1973). “The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis”. Metroeconomica, 25, 1-29.) vertically integrated labor vectors. This calculation leads to the implicit assumption that there is a linear relationship between the employment from each sector and the value of their production. The employment multiplier for each sector (6) (Pasinetti, 1986Pasinetti, L. (1986). “Theory of value: A source of alternative paradigms in Economic Analysis”. In: Baranzini, Scazzieri (eds.), Foundations of Economics. Structures of Inquiry and Economic Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 409-431.) would be determined by:

E j = i = 1 n W n + 1 m i j (6)

mij being the element of matrix Ma obtained from SAM, and

W n + 1 = Y e i X i (7)

where is the employment generated in sector i, and where Xi it is the total output of sector i.

Thus, having the relationship into consideration, we can determine the impact on the employment of a specific economic sector resulting from the changes in production. Therefore, the sectors with the greatest value from the employment multiplier are the ones creating more jobs from receiving an exogenous income injection. By observing the evolution of this indicator, we could verify whether or not the employment sectoral composition will follow the same behavioral dynamic when facing changes to the economic structure.

It is also worth pointing out that the employment generation in an economy resulting from exogenous shock of a specific sector, can be decomposed into a direct effect. This includes the jobs created directly in the affected sector, and into an indirect effect, including the jobs created in the sectors with linkages, especially those sectors with regional suppliers from the sector.

3. MODEL OUTCOMES

The bio-SAM Model for Spain 2010 is comprised by 61 accounts, out of those, 26 represent the branches of activity (referred to the activity in the different productive sectors) These 26 branches of activity appear on Table 2, in which the 12 sectors we considered as “potentially green sectors” have been shaded.

Table 2
Branches of activity of the bio-SAM Model for Spain, 2010

Applying the methodology and analysis previously described to the 61 accounts of the bio-SAM Model for Spain 2010 and considering as endogenous accounts those related to primary factors, the private sector, and branches of activity, we can obtain the countable multiplier matrix with a dimension of 58 x 58. After obtaining the matrix we can differentiate within the different blocks or sub-matrices, based on the accounts incorporated in the set of endogenous accounts, and conduct an interpretation of each of the items.

To classify the “potentially green sectors” in Spain according to their absorption and diffusion capacities and to be able to identify their capacity to generate “potentially green jobs”, we must get the standardized absorption and diffusion coefficients along with their employment multipliers (Cardenete and López, 2015Cardenete, M.A., López, R. (2015). “Análisis del sector aeronáutico en Andalucía y Sevilla”. Economía Industrial, 398, 155-166.: 13-14).

3.1. Analysis of the “potentially green sectors” of the Spanish economy in terms of economic efficiency

First, we have calculated the countable multipliers of the SAM Model for Spain, 2010, in order to determine the absorption and diffusion coefficients of the sector accounts. From there we can obtain Rasmussen’s standardized absorption coefficients (dispersion responsiveness) and Rasmussen’s standardized diffusion coefficients (power of dispersion) to be able to classify the “potentially green sectors” based on it, as shown in Table 3.

Table 3
Analysis of the “potentially green sectors” in the Spanish economy

From Table 3 we can deduct that nearly every “potentially green sector”, besides crops and forestry, show substantial backwards linkage, and therefore, are the driving sectors of the economy. Consequently, any exogenous stimulus related to them, will have a strong impact on the aggregated internal demand of the Spanish economy. Thus, the “potentially green sectors” susceptible to stimulation by policy makers to generate a green economic development, in descending order by dispersion responsiveness, would be livestock, food industry, wood industry, bioenergy, fishing, textile industry, biochemical industry, and water and waste. Particular consideration should be given to the food industry sector, not only because its absorptive capacity (dispersion responsiveness), given it is a key sector of the Spanish economy with substantial backwards linkages (their suppliers essentially come from crops, livestock and fishing), and forward (not including family consumption and exports, this sector’s client is the powerful trade, hospitality and catering business; that is, trade and tourism). In fact, the food industry is the main manufacturing industry in Spain in terms of added value.

In the cases of forestry and crops as independent sectors, a priori, they draw attention due to their low dispersion power even though they are the supplying sectors to the wood industry, first, and to the food industry, second, expecting them to be base sectors. However, the relevancy of their agricultural and forestry exports justifies their independence with respect to the other economic sectors and their dependence to the exterior sector.

3.2. Analysis of the “potentially green sectors” in the Spanish economy in terms of economic efficiency

Similarly, we can calculate the Spanish economy employment multipliers, showing us the expansionary impact final demand shocks have on employment; that is, the responsiveness rate to each sector’s demand, in terms of employment or, in other words, the amount of jobs Spain could create for every million euros pumped into each sector (López Álvarez, 2015López Álvarez, J.M. (2015). Análisis del cambio estructural de la economía andaluza a través de instrumentos de modelización multisectorial [PhD Dissertation], Pablo de Olavide University, Seville (Spain).: 43-44). The employment multipliers from the “potentially green sectors” in Spain are shown in Table 4.

Table 4
Employment multipliers of the “potentially green sectors” in the Spanish economy

Taking this data into account, we could group the ten “potentially green sectors” into three groups according to their capacity for employment creation, direct, indirect, and total, when facing demand changes.

The following are the employment generating sectors above the median, out of all the sectors of the Spanish economy (6.023), as a direct consequence from an exogenous stimulus, in descending order of direct effect: forestry, water and waste, crops, and livestock. These are the four sectors with low-capital intensity and limited absorption of new technologies that could increase labor productivity. Therefore, every exogenous stimulus generating an increase in labor productivity in these sectors will result in a considerable job increase in these sectors.

Secondly, we would have the employment generating sectors above the median, out of all the sectors in the Spanish economy (11.098), as an indirect consequence from the exogenous stimulus, showing in descending order of indirect effect: livestock, wood industry, food industry, bioenergy, fishing, forestry, water and waste, and biochemistry. This group includes the “potentially green sectors”, except from crops and the textile industry. Most of the employment generating indirect effect from these sectors takes place in the trade, hospitality, and catering business, in transportation and communications, as well as in other services and in public administration. This is due to the fact that the sectors must request proposals for specific services in order for their products to reach the consumers or the foreign importers in the specified conditions. As the services in question are stalled in many cases, they required a greater amount of labor for each final unit produced. Although in the case of the food industry, the importance of the indirect effect by employing crops and livestock as supplying sectors is also highlighted. While in the case of livestock, it also generates an important indirect effect by using crops to generate productive inputs for said sector, as well as a noticeable indirect effect on the food industry.

And the sectors generating a total effect above the median, out of all the sectors of the Spanish economy (17.121), in descending order of total effect are: forestry (28.852), water and waste (28.373), livestock (27.262), crops (20.773), wood industry (19.908), and fishing (17.881). This latest data shows that, for each million euros o exogenous stimulus pumped into the Spanish economy, on average, a little over 17 jobs are created. When this million euros is intended to promote forestry it generates almost 29 new jobs in the economy as a whole. While in the case of the water and waste sector, it would create a little over 28 jobs, a little over 27 in livestock, almost 21 in crops, about 20 in the wood industry, and almost 19 in fishing. If we consider the total effects on employment, on a strategy promoting green jobs priority should be given to external stimulus enforcing economic policy measurements, in descending order of total effect to forestry, water and waste, livestock, crops, wood industry and fishing.

4. CONCLUSION

Given the results from our analysis, we can confirm that the selected ten “potentially green sectors” present similarities in terms of their dispersion responsiveness and their power of dispersion. Regarding the dispersion responsiveness (standardized absorption coefficient) only two of the ten sectors show lower responsiveness to the unit, forestry, and crops. If we analyze the power of dispersion (standardized diffusion rate) we could see how eleven out of the ten selected sectors have lower rates compared to the unit, and only the food industry would be above the unit. Thus, out of the ten “potentially green sectors”, only the food industry is a key sector with substantial backward and forward linkages. While the following sectors, livestock, food industry, wood industry, biochemical industry, and water and waste are the driving sectors, with forestry and crops as independent sectors.

Therefore, the “potentially green sectors”, in terms of key and driving sectors which stimulus will generate greater economic impact in Spain would be the food industry (key sector), livestock, wood industry, bioenergy, fishing, textile industry, biochemical industry, and water and waste (driving sectors). This way, by meeting the economic efficiency standards, these ten sectors should be stimulated first during a strategy to promote green economy in Spain.

However, when considering social efficiency criteria, such as the capacity to create green jobs, the priority sectors of said strategy should be the ones with a greater capacity to create jobs (total superior effect to the average of all the sectors of the Spanish economy); that is forestry, water and waste, livestock, crops, wood industry, and fishing.

Hence, when the economic efficiency criteria of the stimulus is combined with its social efficiency criteria, the ten “potentially green sectors” selected should be subject to the stimulus by the policy makers during a strategy to promote green economy and green jobs in Spain. Nevertheless, this conclusion has been reached by applying qualitative technical criteria on economic and social efficiency and requires a series of important tweaks.

If the intention is to transform the Spanish productive structure with the economic stimulus policies to make it more green without having to relinquish economic growth, or job creation. The stimulus must have a qualitative nature (targeting the stimulus), and must also correspond to the environmental efficiency criteria, conditioning their reception until compliance with specific requirements.

So, in the case of crops, the stimulus must be targeted to the organic farming sub-sector, which uses less water for irrigation per hectare. In addition, it avoids using agrochemicals and excludes the transgenic varieties of vegetables. Similar criteria should be applied to the livestock stimulus, targeting it into the organic livestock farming sub-sector, which avoids livestock stabling and feeding animals processed food. Moreover, it excludes the transgenic varieties of livestock and requires consumable goods from organic farming to feed livestock. The same should apply to forestry, targeting the stimulus into the ecoforestry sub-sector, which avoids the irrigation and usage of the transgenic varieties of vegetables and exogenous to the land, and it accommodates the tree harvesting rate to the regeneration rate of deforestation. Fishing deserves specific attention because of the nature of the activity, extracting natural resources from the ocean. In this case the stimulus should be targeted into promoting organic aquaculture (following the organic livestock farming methods), instead of promoting fishing (other than in the cases of overcrowded fishing grounds).

With regards to the food industry the stimulus should be conditioned to the industry demanding products from organic farming, livestock and aquaculture and to give up the usage of transgenic products originating from livestock or plants as well as the usage of plastic containers (due to its high environmental impact). In addition, to encourage people to reuse their own containers (glass and metal preferably) by getting them back at the points of sale (in a circular economy strategy). While in the case of the textile industry only those activities using commodities originating from organic farming and livestock, and have a textile recycling mechanism (in a circular economy strategy) to turn them into new items for brand new textile products (usually lower quality). Moreover, they avoid using commodities originating from oil, hunting or non-organic crops and livestock.

In the case of the wood industry, the stimulus should be conditioned to the use of wood originating from ecoforestry and guarantees its environmental waste is reutilized as items for the bioenergy industry (biomass) (in a circular economy strategy). And in the case of the biochemical industry the stimulus should be targeted into promoting the production of biodegradable containers and packaging (alternating plastic) (also in a circular economy strategy).

With regards to the bioenergy sector, only should be stimulated those activities producing biomass, biodiesel, and bioethanol which supplies originate from waste (tree harvesting or wood industry), also in a circular economy strategy, or from low-utility products for human consumption originating from sustainable resource extraction (such as seaweed), avoiding competition against crops for ground level power supply when generating the supplies for its production. For the water and waste sector (water supply and sanitation), it would be advisable to promote using waste from sewage treatment plants to produce compost and fertilizer (in a circular economy strategy) and to encourage the creation of green domestic and community filters, conditioning the stimulus to these efforts.

Nevertheless, a strategy to promote green economy and green jobs should not only be limited to the “potentially green sectors” identified and studied in this paper but should also go beyond promoting the production of energy originating from renewable sources. The production of electric and solar vehicles, bioconstruction, sustainable tourism, alternative long-haul traffic other than airplanes and ships (for example, the electric railway does not use oil-based fuels), recycling glass and metal, repairing and renting equipment and properties, as well as civil service activities such as environmental administration, environmental education, or preventive health.

REFERENCES

  • Battaglia, M., Cerrini, E., Annesi, N. (2018). “Can environmental agreements represent an opportunity for green jobs? Evidence from two Italian experiences”. Journal of Clearner Production, 175, 257-266. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.12.086
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.12.086
  • Borges, R., Montibeler E.E. (2014). “Input-Output Matrix study: A theoretical frame to study the impact of Brazilian IPI reduction in final demand”. EconomiA 15, 2, 228-241.
  • Cai, W., Wang, C., Chen, J., Wang, S. (2011). “Green economy and green jobs: myth or reality? The case of China’s power generation sector”. Energy, 36, (10), 5994-6003. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2011.08.016
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2011.08.016
  • Campoy-Múñoz, P., Cardenete, M.A., Delgado, M.C. (2017). “Economic impact assessment of food waste reduction on European countries through social accounting matrices”. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 122, (202-209). url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2017.02.010
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2017.02.010
  • Cardenete, M.A., López, R. (2015). “Análisis del sector aeronáutico en Andalucía y Sevilla”. Economía Industrial, 398, 155-166.
  • Cardenete, M.A., Congregado, E., De Miguel, F.J., Pérez, J. (2000). “Análisis comparativo de las economías andaluza y extremeña a través de sus MCS”. Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 15, 47-74.
  • Cardenete, M.A., Fuentes, P., Mainar, A., Rodríguez, C. (2015). “Análisis y explotación mediante mode­los económicos multisectoriales de la Matriz de Contabilidad Social de Andalucía para 2008”. Regional and Sectorial Economic Studies, 15, (1), 153-168.
  • Casares, E.R., García-Salazar, M.G., Sobarzo, H. (2017). “Las Matrices de Contabilidad Social como base de datos y soporte de modelos multisectoriales”. EconoQuantum, 141, 119-142.
  • Cesere, G., Mazzanti, M. (2017). “Green jobs and eco-innovations in European SMEs”. Resource and Energy Economics, 49, 86-98. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.03.003
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.03.003
  • Chapa, J., Ortega, A. (2017). “Carbon tax effects on the poor: A SAM-based approach”. Environmental Research Letters, 12, (9). url: http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa80ed
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa80ed
  • Chenoweth, J., Anderson, A.R., Kumar, P., Hunt, W.F., Chimbwandira, S.J., Moore, T. L. (2018). “The interrelationship of green infrastructure and natural capital”. Land Use Policy, 75, 137-144. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.03.021
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2018.03.021
  • Connolly, K., Allan, G.J., McIntyre, S.G. (2016). “The evolution of green jobs in Scotland: a hybrid approach”. Energy Policy, 88, 355-360. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.10.044
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.10.044
  • Consoli, D., Marin, G., Marzucchi, A., Vona, F. (2016). “Do green jobs differ from non-green jobs in terms of skills and human capital?” Research Policy, 45, (5), 1046-1060. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.02.007
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.02.007
  • D’Amato, D., Droste, N., Allen, B., Kettunen, M., Lähtinen, K., Korhonen, J., Leskinen, P., Matthies, B.D., Toppinen, A. (2017). “Green, Circular, Bio-economy: A comparative analysis of three sustainability avenues”. Journal Cleaner Production, 168, 716-734. url: https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053
    » https://10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.053
  • Dechezleprêtre, A., Sato, M. (2014). The Impacts of Environmental Regulations on Competitiveness. Policy Brief, London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment and The London School of Economics.
  • European Commission. (2010). Europe 2020: A Strategy for Smart, Sustainable and Inclusive Growth COM(2010) 2020 final, Brussels. url: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
    » https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
  • European Commission. (2011). A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low Carbon Economy in 2050 COM(2011) 112 final, Brussels. url: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2009_2014/documents/com/com_com(2011)0112_/com_com(2011)0112_en.pdf
    » https://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2009_2014/documents/com/com_com(2011)0112_/com_com(2011)0112_en.pdf
  • European Commission. (2019). The European Green Deal COM(2019) 640 final. url: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
    » https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52010DC2020&from=ES
  • European Network for Rural Development. (2017). “Transition to the green economy”. EU Rural Review, 23, 4-8.
  • Fuentes, P.D., Mainar, A.J. (2015). “Impacto económico y en el empleo de la Economía Social en España. Un análisis multisectorial”. Revista de Economía Pública, Social y Cooperativa, 83, 63-81.
  • García-Remigio, C.M., Cardenete, M.A., Campoy-Muñoz, P., Venegas-Martínez, F. (2020). “Valoración del impacto de la industria automotriz en la economía mexicana: una aproximación mediante matrices de contabilidad social”. El Trimestre Económico, 87, (346), 437-461. url: https://doi.org/10.20430/ete.v87i346.852
    » https://doi.org/10.20430/ete.v87i346.852
  • Herrán, C. (2012). El camino hacia una economía verde, México, D.F.: Proyecto Energía y Clima de la Fundación Friedrich Ebert.
  • Hess, D.J., Quan, D.M., Skaggs, R., Sudibjo, M. (2018). “Local matters: Political opportunities, spatial scale, and support for green jobs policies”. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 26, 158-170. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eist.2017.03.003
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eist.2017.03.003
  • Hoekstra, R. (2010). A Complete Database of Peer-Reviewed Articles on Environmentally Extended Input-Output Analysis, Sydney: 18th International Input-Output Conference. url: https://www.iioa.org/conferences/18th/papers/files/36_20100614091_Hoekstra-EE-IOoverview-final.pdf
    » https://www.iioa.org/conferences/18th/papers/files/36_20100614091_Hoekstra-EE-IOoverview-final.pdf
  • Hughes, G. (2011). The Myth of Green Jobs, London: The Global Warming Policy Foundation.
  • Jiménez Herrero, L.M., Leiva, A., (2010). Informe empleo verde en una economía sostenible, Madrid: Observatorio de la Sostenibilidad de España y Fundación Biodiversidad.
  • Kahn, M.E., Mansur, E.T. (2013). “Do local energy prices and regulation affect the geographic concentration of employment?” Journal Public Economics, 101(C), 105-114. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.03.002
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.03.002
  • Leontief, W. (1936). “Quantitative Input-Output relations in the economic system of the United States”. Review of Economics and Statistics, 18, 105-125.
  • Loiseau, E., Saikku, L., Antikainen, R., Droste, N., Hansjürgens-Pitkanen, K., Leskinen, P., Kuikman, P., Thomsen, M. (2016). “Green economy and related concepts”. Journal Cleaner Production, 139, 361-371. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.024
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.024
  • López Álvarez, J.M. (2015). Análisis del cambio estructural de la economía andaluza a través de instrumentos de modelización multisectorial [PhD Dissertation], Pablo de Olavide University, Seville (Spain).
  • Mahnkopf, B. (2014). “Desigualdad social o giro a economía verde: respuesta adecuada para la crisis época del capitalismo”. Revista Mundo Siglo XXI, 34. url: https://repositorio.flacsoandes.edu.ec/xmlui/handle/10469/7039
    » https://repositorio.flacsoandes.edu.ec/xmlui/handle/10469/7039
  • Mainar, A.J., Fuentes, P.D., Ferrari, E. (2017a). “The role of bioeconomy sectors and natural resources in EU economies: A social accounting matrix-based analysis approach”. Sustainability, 9, (12), 1-13.
  • Mainar, A.J., Philippidis, G., Sanjuan, A.I. (2017b). Analysis of Structural Patterns in Highly Disaggregated Bioeconomy Sectors by EU Member States Using SAM/IO Multipliers EUR 28591. JRC Technical Reports. European Commission. Joint Research Centre. url: https://doi.org/10.2760/822918
    » https://doi.org/10.2760/822918
  • Malthus, T.R. (1798). An Essay on the Principle of Population, London: Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project.
  • Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., Randers, J., Behrens, W. (1972). The Limits to Growth, Washington, D.C.: Potomac Associates.
  • Mei-Mei, X., Qiao-Mei, L., Wang, C. (2019). “Price transmission mechanism and socio-economic effect of carbon pricing in Beijing: A two-region social accounting matrix analysis”. Journal of Cleaner Production, 211, 134-145. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.116
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.116
  • Morris, A.P., Bogart, W.T., Dorchak, A., Meiners, R.E. (2009). “Green Jobs Myths”. Case Legal Studies Research Paper, 09-15. Illinois Law & Economics Research Paper No. LE09-001. url: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1358423
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1358423
  • Mulatu, A., Wossink, A. (2014). “Environmental Regulation and Location of Industrialized Agricultural Production in Europe”. Land Economics, 90, (3), 509-537.
  • Pasinetti, L. (1973). “The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis”. Metroeconomica, 25, 1-29.
  • Pasinetti, L. (1986). “Theory of value: A source of alternative paradigms in Economic Analysis”. In: Baranzini, Scazzieri (eds.), Foundations of Economics. Structures of Inquiry and Economic Theory Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 409-431.
  • Pearce, D., Markandya, A., Barbier, E. (1989). Blueprint for Green Economy, New York: Earthscan. url: https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203097298
    » https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203097298
  • Pearce, D., Turner, R. K. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • Philippidis, G., Suta, C., Vinyes, C., Caivano, A., Ferrari, E., Ronzon, T., Sanjuan-Lopez, A., Santini, F. (2014). “Observing and analysing the bioeconomy in the EU: Adapting data and tools to new questions and challenges”. Bio-based and Applied Economics 3(1): 83-91.
  • Quesnay, F. (1758). Tableau Economique, London: British Economic Association.
  • Rasmussen, P. (1956). Studies in Intersectorial Relations, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
  • Ronzon, T., Piotrowski, S., Carus, M., Carrez D. (2017). “A systematic approach to understanding and quantifying the EU’s bioeconomy”. Bio-based and Applied Economics, 6, (1). url: http://dx.doi.org/10.13128/BAE-20567
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.13128/BAE-20567
  • Sato, M. (2014). “Embodied carbon in trade: A survey of the empirical literature”. Journal of Economic Surveys, 28, 831-861. url: https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12027
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12027
  • Simon, J.L., Kahn, H. (1984). The Resourceful Earth: A Response to Global 2000, New York: Basil Blackwell.
  • Soza, S., Ramos, C. (2005). “Replanteamiento del análisis estructural a partir del análisis factorial. Una aplicación a las economías europeas”. Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 23, (2), 363-384.
  • Stone, R. (1962). A Social Accounting Matrix for 1960 A Program for Growth, London: Chapman and Hall.
  • Su, B., Ang, B.W. (2012). “Structural decomposition analysis applied to energy and emissions: Some methodological developments”. Energy Economics, 34, 177-188. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.10.009
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.10.009
  • Unay-Gailharda, I., Bojnecb, S. (2019). “The impact of green economy measures on rural employment: Green jobs in farms”. Journal of Cleaner Production, 208, 541-551. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.10.160
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.10.160
  • UNEP. (2011). Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication, Nairobi: United Nations Environment Program.
  • Wei, M., Patadia, S., Kammen, D.M. (2010). “Putting renewable and energy efficiency to work: how many jobs can the clean energy industry generate in the US?” Energy Policy, 38, (2), 919-932. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.10.044
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2009.10.044
  • World Commission on Environment and Development. (1987). Our Common Future, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Yi, H. (2013). “Clean energy policies and green jobs: an evaluation of green jobs in US metropolitan areas”. Energy Policy, 56, 644-652. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.034
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.034
  • Yingzhu, L., Bin, S., Dasgupta, S. (2018). “Structural path analysis of India’s carbon emissions using input-output and social accounting matrix frameworks”. Energy Economics, 76, 457-469. url: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.10.029
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.10.029
  • 1
    The available data does not allow a disaggregated classification of the bioeconomic sectors and neither of the circular economy sectors of the Spanish economy through its SAM; however, we have an approximation to the green economy in Spain thanks to the Spanish bio-SAM prepared by Mainar et al. (2017aMainar, A.J., Fuentes, P.D., Ferrari, E. (2017a). “The role of bioeconomy sectors and natural resources in EU economies: A social accounting matrix-based analysis approach”. Sustainability, 9, (12), 1-13.).
  • 2
    Cereals (paddy rice, wheat, barley, maize, other cereals); vegetables (tomatoes, potatoes, other vegetables); fruits (grapes, other fruits); oilseeds (rape, sunflower, and soya seeds); oil plants (olives, other oil plants); industrial crops (sugar beet, fiber plants, tobacco); and other crops (live plants, other crops).
  • 3
    Extensive livestock production (live bovine, sheep, goats, horses, asses, mules…); intensive livestock production (live swine, poultry); other live animals and animal products; raw milk.
  • 4
    Fishing.
  • 5
    Forestry, logging, and related service activities, energy crops include.
  • 6
    Animal feed, fodder crops, biodiesel by-product oilcake; red meat (meat of bovine, meat of sheep, goats); white meat (meat of swine, poultry); vegetable oils; dairy; rice, processed; sugar, processed; olive oil; wine; beverages and tobacco; other food products).
  • 7
    Wood products, pellets include.
  • 8
    Textiles, wearing apparel and leather.
  • 9
    Biochemicals.
  • 10
    Bioelectricity; biofuel 1st generation (bioethanol, biodiesel); biofuel 2nd generation (biochemical and thermal technology biofuel).
  • 11
    Water distribution, sewerage, waste management and remediation activities.
  • 12
    A Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) represents the functioning of the economy of a territory for a prolonged period, in which its structure remains stable, and collects the monetary flows of the circuit of transactions among the different economic accounts (García-Remigio et al., 2020García-Remigio, C.M., Cardenete, M.A., Campoy-Muñoz, P., Venegas-Martínez, F. (2020). “Valoración del impacto de la industria automotriz en la economía mexicana: una aproximación mediante matrices de contabilidad social”. El Trimestre Económico, 87, (346), 437-461. url: https://doi.org/10.20430/ete.v87i346.852
    https://doi.org/10.20430/ete.v87i346.852...
    ). To appreciate the existence of a structural change in an economy using social accounting matrices, it is necessary to resort to the comparison among the matrices of different periods of time (usually 10 years); however, structural change is not the object of study of this research.
  • JEL Classification: B41; C67; J08; Q57.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    05 May 2023
  • Date of issue
    Apr-Jun 2023

History

  • Received
    14 Sept 2021
  • Accepted
    13 Apr 2022
Centro de Economia Política Rua Araripina, 106, CEP 05603-030 São Paulo - SP, Tel. (55 11) 3816-6053 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: cecilia.heise@bjpe.org.br