Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Radical uncertainty and the effect of transport infrastructure on land prices

Incerteza radical e o efeito da infraestrutura de transporte nos preços da terra

ABSTRACT

Most contributions in the academic literature identify a positive effect of transport infrastructure on land prices. However, their short-run dynamics has not been routinely analyzed. One of the reasons for this lack of research is because neoclassical urban land economics models underlie, in some cases implicitly, most of the available literature on the topic. In this theory, land values converge to their long-term trends regardless of short-term shocks. We build upon post-Keynesian monetary circuit theory to design a spatial urban economics testing framework, building upon the contributions of Abramo (2011Abramo, P. (2011). La Ciudad Caleidoscópica, Coordinación Espacial y Convención Urbana: una Perspectiva Heterodoxa para la Economía Urbana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 4 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota.) and Alfonso (2007Alfonso, O. (2007), Aportes a una teoría de la estructuración residencial urbana. Revista de Economía Institucional 9(17), 241-277, 2017Alfonso, O. (2017), Bogotá en la Encrucijada del Desorden: Estructuras Socioespaciales y Gobernabilidad Metropolitana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 13 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota .). In this tradition, short-term shocks have long-term effects on the spatial distribution of land values due to radical uncertainty. Our case study is Transmetro, a Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) project in Barranquilla (Colombia). We use static and dynamic panel-estimation to test the short-run dynamics of spatial land price adjustments during 2000-2010, including the construction and delivery years 2006-2010. This case study offers a good assessment opportunity because of featuring prominent problems and delays. We find volatile short-run adjustments that run counter to neoclassical predictions, while resembling spatial land price adjustments exposed to radical uncertainty.

KEYWORDS:
Monetary circuit; post-Keynesian economics; urban economics; bus rapid transport; urban land market; metropolization

RESUMO

A maioria das contribuições na literatura acadêmica identifica um efeito positivo da infraestrutura de transporte nos preços da terra. No entanto, sua dinâmica de curto prazo não tem sido analisada rotineiramente. Uma das razões para essa falta de pesquisa é porque os modelos neoclássicos de economia fundiária urbana fundamentam, em alguns casos implicitamente, a maior parte da literatura disponível sobre o tema. Nesta teoria, os valores da terra convergem para suas tendências de longo prazo, independentemente dos choques de curto prazo. Baseamo-nos na teoria do circuito monetário pós-keynesiano para projetar uma estrutura de teste de economia espacial urbana, com base nas contribuições de Abramo (2011Abramo, P. (2011). La Ciudad Caleidoscópica, Coordinación Espacial y Convención Urbana: una Perspectiva Heterodoxa para la Economía Urbana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 4 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota.) e Alfonso (2007Alfonso, O. (2007), Aportes a una teoría de la estructuración residencial urbana. Revista de Economía Institucional 9(17), 241-277, 2017Alfonso, O. (2017), Bogotá en la Encrucijada del Desorden: Estructuras Socioespaciales y Gobernabilidad Metropolitana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 13 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota .). Nesta tradição, choques de curto prazo têm efeitos de longo prazo na distribuição espacial dos valores da terra devido à incerteza radical. Nosso estudo de caso é o Transmetro, um projeto de Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) em Barranquilla (Colômbia). Usamos estimativas de painel estáticas e dinâmicas para testar a dinâmica de curto prazo dos ajustes espaciais dos preços da terra durante 2000-2010, incluindo os anos de construção e entrega de 2006-2010. Este estudo de caso oferece uma boa oportunidade de avaliação por apresentar problemas e atrasos proeminentes. Encontramos ajustes voláteis de curto prazo que vão contra as previsões neoclássicas, ao mesmo tempo que se assemelham a ajustes espaciais de preços de terras expostos a uma incerteza radical.

PALAVRAS-CHAVE:
Circuito monetário; economia pós-keynesiana; economia urbana; transporte rápido de ônibus; mercado de terras urbanas; metropolização

1. INTRODUCTION

There is abundant academic literature regarding the effect of infrastructure on real estate prices (Higgins & Kanaroglou, 2016Higgins, C. D., & Kanaroglou, P. S. (2016). Forty years of modelling rapid transit’s land value uplift in North America: Moving beyond the tip of the iceberg. Transport Reviews, 36(5), 610-634.; Mohammad et al., 2013Mohammad, S. I., Graham, D. J., Melo, P. C., & Anderson, R. J. (2013). A Meta-analysis of the impact of rail projects on land and property values. Transportation Research Part A, 50, 158-170.). However, there are few analyses about its short-term effects. (Devaux et al., 2017Devaux, N., Dubé, J., & Apparicio, P. (2017), Anticipation and post-construction impact of a metro extension on residential values: the case of Laval (Canada), 1995-2013. Journal of Transport Geography 67, 8-19.; Dubé et al., 2018Dubé, J., Legros, D., & Devaux, N. (2018). From bus to tramway: Is there an economic impact of substituting a rapid mass transit system? An empirical investigation accounting for anticipation effect. Transportation Research Part A 110, 73-87.). This relative scarcity of research on short-term adjustments is due to the predominance of Neoclassical economics in urban research. According to Neoclassical theory, urban areas are long-run spatial general equilibrium systems with trends detectable by market agents and government assessors. Short-term real estate price adjustments are simply intermediate steps in the convergence to long-run trends, in which transport infrastructure is fully capitalized into land prices (Wang et al., 2015Wang, Y., et al. (2015), Bus stop, property price and land value tax: A multilevel hedonic analysis with quantile calibration. Land Use Policy 42, 381-391.; Yen et al., 2018Yen, B. et al. (2018), Announcement, construction or delivery: when does value uplift occur for residential properties? Evidence from the Gold Coast Light Rail system in Australia. Land Use Policy 73, 412-422; Park, 2014Park, J. (2014), Land rent theory revisited. Science & Society, 78(1), 88-109.).

In contrast to Neoclassical economics, short-term adjustments are fundamental in Monetary Circuit, a post-Keynesian macroeconomic theory. This theory states that money is endogenously created by the financial system via credit (Cesaratto, 2017Cesaratto, S. (2017), Initial and final finance in the monetary circuit and the theory of effective demand. Metroeconomica 68(2), 228-258.), an inherently uncertain process, where conventional agreements between the government and financial sector are necessary to even ‘create’ capitalism itself (Aglietta & Cartelier, 2002Aglietta, M. & J. Cartelier (2002), Orden monetario de las economías de mercado. Cuadernos de Economía 21(36), 41-75). In this paper we extract an urban economics prediction from Monetary Circuit macroeconomics: in Global South cities the conventional agreements among government-finance-developers are weak, generating ‘urban radical uncertainty’. This is a situation where market agents require incentives and extra official information from city authorities to engage in urban development processes (Abramo, 2011Abramo, P. (2011). La Ciudad Caleidoscópica, Coordinación Espacial y Convención Urbana: una Perspectiva Heterodoxa para la Economía Urbana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 4 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota.; Alfonso, 2017Alfonso, O. (2017), Bogotá en la Encrucijada del Desorden: Estructuras Socioespaciales y Gobernabilidad Metropolitana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 13 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota .; and Bao Nguyen et al., 2017Bao Nguyen, T.; E. Van de Krabben & D. Samsura (2017), A curious case of property privatization: two examples of the tragedy of the anticommons in Ho Chi Minh City-Vietnam. International Journal of Urban Sciences 21(1), 72-90.).

We use a case study to test urban radical uncertainty: the spatial distribution of land prices before, during and after the construction of a Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) project in Barranquilla, Colombia. This project was impacted by significant delays and public controversy. In this case study, the land market did not perform Neoclassical-style convergent short-term price adjustments.

Urban radical uncertainty is a serious problem in the Global South, making ex-ante land valuation an almost insurmountable task. The uncertainty in these urban markets is such that the most convenient funding source for transport infrastructure is debt, which can be subsequently recovered using land exactions and property taxes. This process can be performed only after city-wide spatial markets have fully accommodated construction infrastructure shocks, and long-run trends have been established.

Our paper has five sections, including this introduction. Section two presents the conceptual framework and the empirical strategy. Section three introduces the case study, highlighting its turbulent development process. It also presents the database compilation. The fourth section presents regression results, and section five concludes.

2. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK AND EMPIRICAL STRATEGY

2.1 Two Different Approaches to Uncertainty in Urban Land Markets

Here we explain uncertainty in Neoclassical models, before proceeding to show our alternative approach. In the Neoclassical tradition it is optimal to develop a property when the present value of newer land rents, due to planning or infrastructural changes, equals the present value of the old rents (opportunity cost) plus development cost. Development timing is a moving target which, regardless of short-term uncertainty, can be predicted in the long-run. Figure 1 represents this “predictable uncertainty”.

Figure 1
Land Price, infrastructure, and short-term (predictable) uncertainty

Figure 1 shows the effect of public works on the price of a plot of land. The positive price trend reflects ongoing, city-wide growth, with observable prices represented by continuous lines. Public works temporarily accelerate the positive price trend, represented by a steeper, dashed line. When the infrastructure is delivered for public use, land prices return to the long-run trend, although with a higher absolute value. Well-informed sellers can anticipate the dashed-line increase, if: 1) buyers do not know the trend and are willing to pay the sellers’ price; or 2) buyers are not willing to pay the sellers’ price, but the price difference between t 1 and t n , is high enough to compensate the sellers’ opportunity cost of not using the land during that period.

In Figure 1, the predictable delivery of public works at t n allows the agents to base their decisions on long-run trends. This is uncertainty in Neoclassical terms (Loasby, 2011Loasby, B. (2011), Uncertainty and imagination, illusion and order: Shackleian connections. Cambridge Journal of Economics 35(4), 771-783.). Devaux et al. (2017Devaux, N., Dubé, J., & Apparicio, P. (2017), Anticipation and post-construction impact of a metro extension on residential values: the case of Laval (Canada), 1995-2013. Journal of Transport Geography 67, 8-19.) and Dubé et al. (2018Dubé, J., Legros, D., & Devaux, N. (2018). From bus to tramway: Is there an economic impact of substituting a rapid mass transit system? An empirical investigation accounting for anticipation effect. Transportation Research Part A 110, 73-87.) find spatial evidence of such processes, even when not testing for uncertainty in the sense we do here.

Neoclassical economics has short-run uncertainty with long-run predictability because money is exogenous in its macroeconomic core model. Money is created when the central bank supplies it to commercial banks, and market agents merely adapt to this exogenous money supply in the long run. With the certainty of exogenous and perfectly inelastic (to the interest rate) money supply by the central bank, observable short-term price adjustments always converge to the long-run money supply (money neutrality).

In contrast to the Neoclassical approach, in the Monetary Circuit, a post-Keynesian macroeconomic theory, money creation is endogenous and occurs when commercial banks lend it to market agents (Penido, 1999Penido, M. (1999), Moeda endógena e passividade bancária: uma análise crítica da abordagem. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 19(4), 114-133.; Palley, 2017Palley, T. (2017), The theory of endogenous money and the LM schedule: prelude to a reconstruction of IS-LM. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 37(1), 3-22.). There is no certainty that the central bank automatically determines commercial bank loans and economic activity; furthermore, market agents request loans only if they perceive that demand for their products is going to be strong enough to pay back the loans. In other words, the monetary circuit is exposed to an endogenous and unavoidable source of uncertainty.

Economic recessions have offered quasi-experimental evidence in favor of Monetary Circuit macroeconomics, where central banks have given money to commercial banks, but these banks have been unable to lend it out, regardless of low or zero interest rates. This is evidence that money is created when agents take it from commercial banks in the form of loans, as opposed to when central banks send it to the commercial banks (Deleidi & Fontana, 2019Deleidi, M. & G. Fontana (2019), Money Creation in the Eurozone: An Empirical Assessment of the Endogenous and the Exogenous Money Theories. Review of Political Economy 31:4, 559-581).

An efficient monetary circuit requires a stable and trustworthy system of institutional arrangements between the government and financial institutions and differs by countries. These institutional arrangements are the product of very long-run historical processes, which have determined the evolution of capitalism itself (Aglietta & Cartelier, 2002Aglietta, M. & J. Cartelier (2002), Orden monetario de las economías de mercado. Cuadernos de Economía 21(36), 41-75; Fratianni & Spinelli, 2006Fratianni, M. & F. Spinelli (2006), Italian city-states and financial evolution. European Review of Economic History 10(3), 257-278).

Urban development is a sub-circuit of the macroeconomic monetary circuit, determined by both national and local institutional arrangements. In developed countries, the arrangements operate reasonably well; the process resembles autonomous market-driven urban dynamics. Government interventions are minor corrections to an on-going market process. In contrast, in Latin America the arrangements are weak, because most of the money creation is done by government agencies, using external loans intermediated by the central bank. That is, public reassurance is needed by the monetary urban sub-circuits (Alfonso, 2007Alfonso, O. (2007), Aportes a una teoría de la estructuración residencial urbana. Revista de Economía Institucional 9(17), 241-277; Abramo, 2011Abramo, P. (2011). La Ciudad Caleidoscópica, Coordinación Espacial y Convención Urbana: una Perspectiva Heterodoxa para la Economía Urbana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 4 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota.).

Monetary Circuit theory does not have a microeconomics subfield as such. However, its logic can be extended to the institutional arrangements required to launch urban development processes. Analyses along this line describe how market agents require regulatory action, infrastructure development and incentives from local governments, before launching development projects (Almeida & Monte-Mor, 2017Almeida, R. & R. Monte-Mor (2017), Renda da terra e o espaço urbano capitalista contemporâneo. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 37(2), 417-436.; Cirolia & Berrisford, 2017Cirolia, L. & S. Berrisford (2017), ‘Negotiated planning’: Diverse trajectories of implementation in Nairobi, Addis Ababa, and Harare. Habitat International 59, 71-79; Von Mettenheim, 2006Von Mettenheim, K. (2006), Still the Century of Government Savings Banks? The Caixa Econômica Federal. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 26(1), 39-57).

Figure 2 represents radical uncertainty, which occurs when the delivery date of public works cannot be guaranteed. Market agents want to anticipate the land value increase; however, the long-run trend is also moving at the moments t n , t n+1 , and t n+2 . Empirical analyses will not depict a smooth transition towards the long-run trend line (the curved continuous line in Figure 1), as the trend line cannot be determined in the first place (Alfonso, 2017Alfonso, O. (2017), Bogotá en la Encrucijada del Desorden: Estructuras Socioespaciales y Gobernabilidad Metropolitana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 13 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota .).

Figure 2
Land price, infrastructure, and radical uncertainty

Figure 2 represents our case study, where market agents cannot make decisions based on long-run trends. We derive two empirical hypotheses from the figure: 1) the short-term spatial adjustments to the BRT construction are not consistent (regression parameters changes do not have same sign). The reason for such inconsistency is that: 2) market agents cannot a-priori determine the long-run price trends. These are the differences in the price behavior between the interval [t 0:t n ]of figure 1, and the interval [t 0:t n+m ] of figure 2. We test these hypotheses by verifying short-term price fluctuations as a function of distance to transport infrastructure, on a baseline citywide model of land prices. This baseline model is presented in section 2.2.

2.2 Spatial Dynamics and Empirical Strategy

Figure 3 represents a Neoclassical urban economics model. The continuous lines R t0 (East and West) are initial period t0 bid-rent functions, decreasing as a function of distance to the center (CBD) in every direction. The city limit is where the bid-rent functions intersect the Rural Rents (RR). When a BRT is built on the east radial street but not on the west, the model predicts three adjustment stages: 1) all the locations to the east are more accessible, diminishing location pressure and the slope of the bid rent function to ER t1 ; 2) development migration from the west side drops its bid-rent function to WR t2 and its urban limit to WD t2 ; and 3) the development potential has migrated to the east side, shifting-up the bid-rent to ER t2 , with city limit ED t2 .

Figure 3
City-wide distribution of land rents after transport improvement

The baseline model of Figure 3 can be observed using panel estimation on data that includes these moments: before, during and immediately after, transport improvement (Yen et al., 2018Yen, B. et al. (2018), Announcement, construction or delivery: when does value uplift occur for residential properties? Evidence from the Gold Coast Light Rail system in Australia. Land Use Policy 73, 412-422). Figure 3 represents the BRT construction effect city-wide, not just on its vicinity, which is analyzed in the accessibility gradient of Figure 4.

Figure 4
Price adjustment in the BRT vicinity

The initial bid-rent function r t0 in Figure 4 already assigns higher prices to locations closer to the original radial road. This distribution is superimposed to every D t ring location in Figure 3 (any location at the same distance from the city center). When the BRT is built, land rents increase to r t1 in Figure 4. However, subsequent development migration fills-in the accessibility gradient up to r t2 . Notice that r t2 is higher but has the same slope as r t0 , because the accessibility conditions to the radial road that contains the BRT have not changed. In the empirical section below, we use an influence buffer of 500 meters to portray these land rent movements in relation to BRT. This distance is used for visualization purposes only; it does not have any effect on regression results because our regression all the metro area data1 1 Literature on the interactions between transport and real estate customarily uses pre-determined buffers of impact in data collection and estimation. That is, quasi-experimental research designs that dismiss analyses at the city-wide scale. .

To detect the above-described processes, garzwe implement the regressions described by equations (1) and (2). These regressions represent a baseline Neoclassical model: r i,t is the land price per square meter at neighborhood i and time t; which decreases in the Distance to Center and to BRT, requiring negative parameters for γ (R t in figure 3) and δ (r t in figure 4). The model also requires correct signs of the β g parameters for the X control variables2 2 The expected and obtained signs for these parameters are discussed in section 4. .

r i , t = α + γ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ D i s t B R T i , t + ρ B R T t + n + π B R T t + n · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g X i , t + i + ε i , t (1)

r i , t = α + γ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ D i s t B R T i , t + φ B R T t + n + m + σ B R T t + n + m · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g X i , t + i + ε i , t (2)

We use spatially controlled Difference in Differences (DiD) estimation to detect the short-term fluctuations, by sequentially adding period (BRT t+n ) and year (BRT t+n+m ) dummy variables. These dummies have the value 1 during the construction period (t+n) and for every construction year (t+n+m), and are zero otherwise. The dummies shift the key parameters of the described baseline model: The shifts from ER t0 to ER t1 in Figure 3, and from r t0 to r t1 in Figure 4, require positive ρ and negative π in equation (1). A smooth transition to the long-run trend is represented by the shift from ER t1 to ER t2 in Figure 3, and from r t1 to r t2 in Figure 4, and requires positive φ and negative σ in equation (2). In addition, σ must have a lower absolute value period-by-period, i.e.: less negative in (t+n+2) than in (t+n+1). A less strict test requires the mere consistency of the changes in σ, either positive or negative. Changes with a consistent direction (same sign) at every (t+n+m) period, would be evidence of converging with the long-run trend of Figure 1. A fluctuating sign of σ will resemble the prediction problems of Figure 2. ϵ i are neighborhood panel effects; and ε i,t are regression residuals.

Our model can portray two types of uncertainty: 1) if the parameter γ is consistently negative in any of the specifications, the city-level structure resembles Figure 3, and there are detectable long-run trends towards which to converge; and 2) if the sign of γ fluctuates with the introduction of the construction period (t+n) and/or the yearly (t+n+m) dummies, the uncertainty is such that it is impossible for market agents to even perceive the long-run trends by zone3 3 Recent contributions by Devaux et al. (2017) and Dubé et al. (2018), detect similar fluctuations in their city gradient and Distance to BRT parameters. However, they do not discuss the underlying theoretical model, emphasizing the technical spatial analysis details instead. .

Our second set of tests is performed in equations (3) and (4), where we correct the implicit trend using a positive (because of population and economic growth) Auto-Regressive (AR) component θ:

r i , t = α + θ r i , t - 1 + γ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ D i s t B R T i , t + ρ B R T t + n + π B R T t + n · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g X i , t + i + ε i , t (3)

r i , t = α + θ r i , t - 1 + γ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ D i s t B R T i , t + φ B R T t + n + m + σ B R T t + n + m · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g X i , t + i + ε i , t (4)

Finally, we use dynamic estimation in equations (5) and (6), to eliminate the effect of trends in all the variables while ruling out regression endogeneity. We implement Arellano-Bond panel in first-differences (θ represent first-difference), differencing-out the constant and panel effects, and including lags of all the variables as instruments:

Δ r i , t = θ Δ r i , t - 1 + γ Δ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ Δ D i s t B R T i , t + ρ Δ B R T t + n + π Δ B R T t + n · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g Δ X i , t + e i , t (5)

Δ r i , t = θ Δ r i , t - 1 + γ Δ D i s t C e n t e r i , t + δ Δ D i s t B R T i , t + φ Δ B R T t + n + m + σ Δ B R T t + n + m · D i s t B R T i , t + Σ β g Δ X i , t + e i , t (6)

In summary, we have a sequential testing framework. First, we estimate a baseline urban land market where parameters must have their expected signs. In the second stage, we add construction period and year dummies, and their interactions with Distance to BRT. These are the Difference-in-Differences (DiD) test parameters. We want to verify: 1) the consistency (same sign) of the short-run spatial adjustments to the BRT construction; and 2) if the inclusion of dummies and interactions changes the signs of the baseline model parameters. In the third stage, we verify all the results using dynamic estimation.

3. CASE STUDY AND DATA

Barranquilla is the fourth largest Metropolitan Area in Colombia. Located at the confluence of the Magdalena River and the Caribbean Sea, its conurbation includes the neighboring municipality of Soledad. Barranquilla Metro has governability problems and a weak institutional structure (Perez-Valbuena et al., 2016Perez-Valbuena, G.; J. Ayala-Garcia & E. Chirivi-Bonilla (2016), Urbanización y compromiso comunitario: cinco estudios de caso sobre infraestructura social en educación y salud. Revista de Economía del Caribe 18, 140-159; Arellana et al., 2021Arellana, J.; D. Oviedo, L. Guzman & V. Alvarez (2021), Urban transport planning and access inequalities: A tale of two Colombian cities. Research in Transportation Business & Management, 40, 100554.; Alfonso, 2009Alfonso, O. (2009), Metropolítica: un análisis de algunas experiencias metropolitanas globales. Cadernos Metropole, 21(1), 53-74.)4 4 In recent years Barranquilla, although not Soledad, has improved its indicators of institutional performance, increasing property tax collection and revenue administration efficiency. .

We are focusing on Barranquilla-Soledad, even though the Metro Area includes other three municipalities: Galapa, Malambo, and Puerto Colombia. The reason is that Barranquilla and Soledad have the clearest conurbation phenomena. Conurbation between Barranquilla and Puerto Colombia was incipient during 2000-2010, and no BRT connection was developed or planned.

Barranquilla-Soledad 2000-2010 is an interesting case study because the construction of Transmetro, its BRT system, had extreme delays. A transport infrastructure project with a long and convoluted construction process during which the weak institutional arrangements supporting urban development city-wide were readily apparent. Transmetro provides an opportunity to examine radical uncertainty as characterized in Figure 2.

Barranquilla’s Transmetro is part of the 2000s wave of Colombian BRTs, inspired in the model of Bogota’s Transmilenio (Jaramillo et al., 2012Jaramillo, C.; C. Lizárraga & A. Grindlay (2012), Spatial disparity in transport social needs and public transport provision in Santiago de Cali (Colombia). Journal of Transport Geography 24, 340-357; Combs, 2017Combs, T. (2017), Examining changes in travel patterns among lower wealth households after BRT investment in Bogotá, Colombia. Journal of Transport Geography 60, 11-20). The national government provided a large portion of the funding for Transmetro construction. This was seen by some as a central government attempt to curry favor with local governments to gain future political support (Semana, 2006Semana (2006), Romance Caribe, 5/19/2006. https://www.semana.com/on-line/articulo/romance-caribe/78949-3
https://www.semana.com/on-line/articulo/...
).

Transmetro works started in November of 2005, with completion scheduled for 2007. However, the original delivery date was not met, underperforming in relation to comparable cities (Pereira, Bucaramanga). The inauguration of the first station was surrounded by local corruption scandals (La Silla Vacía, 2010La Silla Vacía (2010), La Mala Hora de Alex Char, 21/11/2010. https://lasillavacia.com/historia/19978
https://lasillavacia.com/historia/19978...
; El Heraldo, 2011El Heraldo (2011), A la política le cogí verdadero miedo: Guillermo Hoenigsberg, 03/Agosto/2011. https://www.elheraldo.co/judicial/a-la-pol-tica-le-cog­-verdadero­­-miedo­-guillermo-hoenigsberg-32014
https://www.elheraldo.co/judicial/a-la-p...
). The project, originally projected to cost 310,000 million pesos, was completed in 2010 at a cost of 750,000 million pesos (Portafolio, 2010Portafolio (2010), Prende motores el Transmetro de Barranquilla, 06/04/2010. https://www.portafolio.co/economia/finanzas/prende-motores-transmetro-barranquilla-374332
https://www.portafolio.co/economia/finan...
).

Figure 5 shows Barranquilla’s TransMetro two lines and 17 stations. The first line departs from Portal de Soledad in the southeast and goes through Avenida Murillo (Calle 45) into downtown. The second line departs from the Barranquillita market, close to the Magdalena River, and heads northwest across Avenida Olaya Herrera (Carrera 46) to Joe Arroyo terminal (Calle 74). Figure 5 includes a background of the built environment by blocks, including their estratos for Barranquilla-Soledad. Estrato is a national socio-spatial classification used to cross-subsidize utilities’ bills by income groups. The Colombian Statistics Agency (DANE) does not report income data at the level of blocks or neighborhoods, and social researchers proxy it using estrato. There are six estratos. One is the lowest (poorer) estrato and Six is the highest (wealthier). Barranquilla has the six estratos, while Soledad, a smaller and poorer municipality, has only One-Three. Elite housing and commercial activities, including landmarks Buenavista Shopping Mall and El Prado Office Center, are located in the north-northwest (the highest estratos) areas of Barranquilla. The south and southeast areas are middle-income residential, while the southwest is industrial and low-income residential. The downtown and river margin are predominantly industrial and working-class commercial.

Figure 5
Barranquilla-Soledad, Transmetro and Estratos

Our database comprises 4,874 certified geocoded appraisals for the period 2000-2010. The appraisals include yearly information on use, built area, construction age, land plot size (or imputed land plot size) and value. The appraisals were conducted by the Local Appraisers Association (Lonja de Propiedad Raíz de Barranquilla), and we compile them into 62 neighborhoods, which are our spatial unit of analysis5 5 We must clarify that Colombian Lonjas are private but regulated institutions, and appraisals can be legally and technically challenged. Property Valuation is a relatively established and trustworthy professional activity. Lonja de Barranquilla uses the database to produce its yearly land prices reports, and to support its department of technical analysis and valuation (Payares, 2012). . We limit our database to the 62 neighborhoods with available land value information in all the years, to perform panel estimation.

We use appraisals because: 1) we do not have any large transaction-based database (which in any case would mix improvements and land); and 2) idiosyncrasies of buyers and sellers might affect transactions, while appraisals respond to valuators’ mental models (Garza & Lizieri, 2019Garza, N. & C. Lizieri (2019), An empirical approach to land monopoly: A case study of the city of Barranquilla, Colombia. Urban Studies, 56(10), 1931-1950). These valuators are informed agents, whom in our theoretical framework can be affected only by radical uncertainty, not by lack of knowledge or irrationality. Figure 6 uses natural breaks to depict the land price per M2 in three different years (2000, 2005 and 2010), including the spatial distribution of the appraisals (our data source), and their average by neighborhoods (our spatial analysis unit).

Figure 6
Land prices per M2 by observation and neighborhood (constant COP$ 2016)*

Our empirical approach builds on a growing body of work that uses panel estimation in Difference-in-Differences (DiD) spatial assessments of transport infrastructure and property prices. From a methodological point of view, we extend panel DiD assessments because:

  1. We use land price appraisals, not repeat sales databases, which are scarce in most Global South cities due to land informality. Our database of appraisals simulates a ‘census’ because it includes all the appraisals performed by licensed agents in the Barranquilla-Soledad area, even in markets of informal origin.

  2. Appraisals smooth-out individual idiosyncrasies. Therefore, counter theoretical short-term price adjustments cannot be attributed to irrationality or market agents’ ignorance.

  3. Our land price appraisals exclude the value associated with improvements, which is not a pure financial asset, and therefore not explained by either the canonical Neoclassical or our post-Keynesian theories.

  4. Our database includes all the land uses, not just residential real estate.

Table 1 shows the variables used in the empirical section. Property Types is the neighborhood average of properties by land use (average of dummies by property). Stations is the neighborhood average of dummies by property for which the closest station is in the corresponding TransMetro section. According to our baseline model Distance to Sub-Centers (Downtown, Buenavista, Prado, Stadium) should have a negative effect on land prices.

Table 1
Descriptive statistics of panel variables by neighborhood

Our panel database is relatively small (62 Cross-section units 11 Periods=682 observations), and our regression analyses require time-lags (AR), first differences, and instrumental variables. Therefore, we limit the number of baseline model variables to six, including: Distance to BRT; Distance to best-fit Subcenter (Prado in this case); Built Total M2; Distance to closest station (stations by TransMetro section), and two Property Types chosen using a stepwise procedure. Descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1.

4. REGRESSION RESULTS

In this section we perform the tests proposed in section 2. In section 4.1 we perform the linear panel regression equations (1) and (2), and then, the trend-corrected equations (3) and (4). Section 4.2 presents the results of the same regressions using Instrumental Variables (IV) to control endogeneity. In section 4.3 results of the dynamic panel (equations 5 and 6) are presented. All the methods produce similar results, reported in tables in the Appendix APPENDIX: REGRESSION RESULTS A1 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 13.135*** 14.632*** 13.554*** 12.945*** 14.129*** 13.273*** 14.367*** 14.297*** 14.402*** 14.461*** 14.566*** Distance to BRT -0.060*** -0.234*** -0.092*** -0.045*** -0.192*** -0.071** -0.212*** -0.215*** -0.224*** -0.225*** -0.245*** Distance to Prado -0.171*** -0.061* -0.134*** -0.166*** -0.047 -0.129*** -0.051 -0.050 -0.053 -0.058* -0.053 Estrato Average 0.595*** -0.095* 0.352*** 0.600*** -0.054 0.367*** -0.065 -0.035 -0.061 -0.045 -0.061 Built M2 0.067*** 0.009 0.030** 0.059*** 0.002 0.026* -0.002 0.005 0.007 0.004 0.007 Type Commercial 0.154* -0.034 -0.115 0.210** 0.002 -0.050 -0.033 0.002 -0.005 -0.017 -0.011 Type Residential -0.372*** -0.246*** -0.314*** -0.323*** -0.205*** -0.241*** -0.234*** -0.218*** -0.216*** -0.234*** -0.234*** Stations Soledad 0.159*** 0.056 -0.079 0.157*** 0.066 -0.077 0.054 0.058 0.067 0.052 0.054 Stations North 0.119*** -0.035 0.135*** 0.127*** -0.010 0.142*** -0.015 -0.016 -0.019 -0.027 -0.011 D_After 0.340** 0.314*** 0.360** 0.078*** 0.064*** 0.061*** 0.042*** 0.032** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.041* -0.037** -0.041* D_2006 0.174 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.040* D_2007 0.297* D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.047* D_2008 0.232 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.038 D_2009 -0.244 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.045* D_2010 0.150 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.006 R2 (adjusted) 0.770 0.892 0.251 0.774 0.897 0.273 0.901 0.897 0.896 0.897 0.902 S.E. of Regression 0.288 0.203 0.222 0.287 0.201 0.220 0.199 0.201 0.201 0.200 0.200 Breush-Pagan 0.000 0.000 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Levin, Lin & Chu 0.001 0.006 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A2 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 4.355*** 11.744*** 4.875*** 4.455*** 11.689*** 4.963*** 11.923*** 11.797*** 11.715*** 11.720*** 12.186*** AR (1) 0.671*** 0.216*** 0.620*** 0.664*** 0.191*** 0.613*** 0.173*** 0.191*** 0.200*** 0.202*** 0.179*** Distance to BRT -0.011 -0.225*** -0.022* -0.017 -0.200*** -0.028* -0.201*** -0.214*** -0.217*** -0.218*** -0.244*** Distance to Prado -0.061*** -0.033 -0.051** -0.062*** -0.020 -0.052** -0.017 -0.023 -0.024 -0.026 -0.025 Estrato Average 0.229*** -0.092* 0.280*** 0.240*** -0.048 0.287*** -0.051 -0.038 -0.052 -0.039 -0.050 Built M2 0.025* 0.000 0.041*** 0.023* -0.008 0.040*** -0.011 -0.007 -0.005 -0.006 -0.006 Type Commercial 0.085 -0.029 -0.042 0.113 0.016 -0.011 -0.014 0.018 0.014 0.008 0.015 Type Residential -0.265*** -0.253*** -0.301*** -0.249*** -0.222*** -0.280*** -0.241*** -0.233*** -0.223*** -0.237*** -0.242*** Stations Soledad 0.082*** -0.008 0.085** 0.083*** 0.010 0.086** -0.006 0.006 0.012 -0.015 0.006 Stations North 0.040 -0.023 0.071** 0.041 0.005 0.069** 0.009 0.004 0.001 -0.006 0.013 D_After -0.021 0.186* -0.019 0.082*** 0.070*** 0.070*** 0.051*** 0.044*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.010 -0.017 0.009 D_2006 0.219 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.044** D_2007 0.078 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.015 D_2008 0.095 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.018 D_2009 -0.367** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.062*** D_2010 0.243 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.021 R2 (adjusted) 0.883 0.915 0.790 0.888 0.919 0.791 0.922 0.918 0.918 0.919 0.922 S.E. of Regression 0.229 0.201 0.232 0.228 0.198 0.231 0.196 0.198 0.198 0.196 0.196 Breush-Pagan 0.270 0.349 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A3 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 13.036*** 97.213 15.921*** 12.539*** 83.919 15.263*** 15.397*** 15.963*** 13.375*** 14.373*** 14.556*** Distance to BRT -0.030 0.084 -0.164*** -0.026 -0.183 -0.249*** -0.373*** -0.260*** -0.297*** -0.295*** -0.314*** Distance to Prado -0.107*** 0.076 -0.277*** -0.093*** -1.501 -0.169* -0.125 -0.233*** -0.027 -0.062 -0.059 Estrato Average 0.554*** -0.453 0.145* 0.554*** -0.294 0.057 0.006 -0.064 -0.054 -0.041 -0.048* Built M2 0.014 -0.027 -0.004 0.014 0.099 -0.007 0.009 -0.012 0.044 -0.006 0.006 Type Commercial 0.360 -1.255 -2.067*** 0.787*** -6.196 -1.428*** -0.846* -1.481*** 0.365 -0.837*** -0.894*** Type Residential -0.879*** -0.873 -0.685*** -0.552*** -0.006 -0.317* 0.021 -0.196 0.587 0.021 -0.049 Stations Soledad 0.149*** -166.206 -0.136 0.135*** -457.200 -0.264* -0.292 -0.283** -0.318** -0.284 -0.476* Stations North 0.284*** 105.172 0.414** 0.287*** -41.293 0.619*** 0.718*** 0.591*** 0.822*** 0.904*** 0.850** D_After 0.433* -0.611 -0.003 0.150** 0.034 0.171*** 0.201*** 0.132*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.043 0.112 0.018 D_2006 -1.155 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) 0.169 D_2007 -0.201 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.073 D_2008 5.456 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.776 D_2009 1.940 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.300 D_2010 -2.279 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.328 R2 (adjusted) 0.773 -25.247 -0.174 0.815 -11.409 -0.102 -0.134 -0.332 -0.726 -0.261 -0.152 S.E. of Regression 0.319 8.684 0.296 0.305 3.248 0.249 0.238 0.270 0.306 0.253 0.231 Hausman 0.993 0.997 0.998 0.996 0.956 1.000 0.999 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 5.038 0.006 2.345 5.630 0.001 0.176 0.096 0.177 0.099 0.044 0.000 Instrument Rank 10 10 10 12 12 12 13 13 13 13 13 P-Value (J-Statistic) 0.025 0.938 0.126 0.018 0.974 0.675 0.757 0.674 0.753 0.834 0.965 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A4 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 0.543 -17.410 7.724*** 0.584 34.097 2.466*** 2.301*** 2.092*** 3.437*** 2.316*** 10.126*** AR (1) 0.957*** 0.445 0.518*** 0.970*** 0.215 0.814*** 0.797*** 0.811*** 0.590*** 0.771*** 0.390*** Distance to BRT -0.021 -0.298 -0.121*** -0.056** -0.328 -0.086*** -0.012 -0.043*** 0.056** -0.009 0.066 Distance to Prado -0.038 0.279 -0.159*** -0.034 -0.715 -0.037*** -0.038* -0.039*** -0.048** -0.036* -0.141*** Estrato Average 0.026 -0.261 0.081*** 0.030 -0.185 0.124*** 0.126** 0.104*** 0.217*** 0.133*** 0.124*** Built M2 0.047** -0.047 0.036*** 0.048** 0.077 0.061*** 0.051*** 0.065*** 0.107*** 0.061*** -0.135*** Type Commercial 0.154 1.261 -0.589*** 0.139 -3.179 0.387*** 0.302 0.581*** 1.241*** 0.613*** -4.223*** Type Residential 0.208 -0.025 -0.020 0.208 0.364 0.242*** 0.144 0.385*** 0.735*** 0.356*** -1.819*** Stations Soledad 0.043 104.565 -0.016 0.043 -139.997 0.042** 0.046* 0.032* 0.035 0.034 -0.166*** Stations North -0.025 31.976 0.141*** -0.031 -10.580 0.001 0.025 0.000 0.041 0.022 0.602*** D_After -0.413* -0.392 -0.525*** 0.043 0.010 0.118*** 0.063*** -0.089** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.063** 0.075 0.084*** D_2006 1.012 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.156 D_2007 0.214 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.003 D_2008 8.439*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -1.207*** D_2009 2.511 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.351 D_2010 19.139*** D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -2.669*** R2 (adjusted) 0.887 0.033 0.311 0.886 0.090 0.728 0.752 0.705 0.326 0.676 -6.031 S.E. of Regression 0.271 1.019 0.238 0.273 1.062 0.268 0.255 0.279 0.421 0.292 0.774 Hausman 0.198 0.266 1.000 0.999 1.000 0.031 1.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 0.260 0.119 0.204 0.255 0.110 0.166 0.995 0.079 0.014 0.091 0.000 Instrument Rank 11 11 11 13 13 13 14 14 14 14 14 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.610 0.730 0.651 0.613 0.740 0.684 0.319 0.779 0.907 0.763 0.998 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A5 Dynamic Panel GMM - First Differences - Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (White Period) GMM 1 GMM 2 GMM 3 GMM 4 GMM 5 GMM 6 GMM 7 AR (1) 0.410*** 0.785*** 0.491*** 0.185*** -0.280*** 0.384*** 0.640*** Distance to BRT -0.414*** -3.323*** -0.104*** -0.228*** -0.689*** -0.419*** -0.303*** Distance to Prado 0.061 -0.232** -0.041 -0.102*** -5.569*** -0.048 0.366*** Estrato Average -2.538*** -1.712*** -0.084** -0.131*** -0.257* -2.246*** -0.528*** Built M2 -0.073*** -0.031** -0.130*** 0.004 -0.343*** -0.168*** -0.157*** Type Commercial -0.378*** -0.951*** -1.379*** 0.143** -1.273*** -0.412*** 0.130 Type Residential -0.189*** 0.162* -0.259*** -0.007 0.668*** -0.152*** 0.032 Stations Soledad -0.246** 0.574*** -0.962*** 0.008 1.524*** -0.160* 3.103*** Stations North -0.051 -0.258* -0.024 -0.010 -4.257*** -0.260*** 0.602*** D_After -25.796*** 0.097*** 0.084*** 0.087*** -0.002 0.016*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 3.649*** D_2006 0.606*** D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.099*** D_2007 -0.477*** D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.069*** D_2008 -1.051*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) 0.131*** D_2009 0.536*** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.064** D_2010 -0.264 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.059 R2 (adjusted) S.E. of Regression 0.517 1.154 0.406 0.289 1.345 0.503 0.481 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 46.646 49.911 53.054 51.411 47.681 47.149 48.584 Instrument Rank 54 56 57 57 57 57 55 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.405 0.284 0.191 0.237 0.364 0.385 0.258 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (WhitePeriod) Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit , and in graphs of their predicted land price time-series in the text.

4.1 Static Panels: Linear Regression with and without AR

Figures 7A and 7B below, and Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix APPENDIX: REGRESSION RESULTS A1 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 13.135*** 14.632*** 13.554*** 12.945*** 14.129*** 13.273*** 14.367*** 14.297*** 14.402*** 14.461*** 14.566*** Distance to BRT -0.060*** -0.234*** -0.092*** -0.045*** -0.192*** -0.071** -0.212*** -0.215*** -0.224*** -0.225*** -0.245*** Distance to Prado -0.171*** -0.061* -0.134*** -0.166*** -0.047 -0.129*** -0.051 -0.050 -0.053 -0.058* -0.053 Estrato Average 0.595*** -0.095* 0.352*** 0.600*** -0.054 0.367*** -0.065 -0.035 -0.061 -0.045 -0.061 Built M2 0.067*** 0.009 0.030** 0.059*** 0.002 0.026* -0.002 0.005 0.007 0.004 0.007 Type Commercial 0.154* -0.034 -0.115 0.210** 0.002 -0.050 -0.033 0.002 -0.005 -0.017 -0.011 Type Residential -0.372*** -0.246*** -0.314*** -0.323*** -0.205*** -0.241*** -0.234*** -0.218*** -0.216*** -0.234*** -0.234*** Stations Soledad 0.159*** 0.056 -0.079 0.157*** 0.066 -0.077 0.054 0.058 0.067 0.052 0.054 Stations North 0.119*** -0.035 0.135*** 0.127*** -0.010 0.142*** -0.015 -0.016 -0.019 -0.027 -0.011 D_After 0.340** 0.314*** 0.360** 0.078*** 0.064*** 0.061*** 0.042*** 0.032** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.041* -0.037** -0.041* D_2006 0.174 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.040* D_2007 0.297* D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.047* D_2008 0.232 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.038 D_2009 -0.244 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.045* D_2010 0.150 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.006 R2 (adjusted) 0.770 0.892 0.251 0.774 0.897 0.273 0.901 0.897 0.896 0.897 0.902 S.E. of Regression 0.288 0.203 0.222 0.287 0.201 0.220 0.199 0.201 0.201 0.200 0.200 Breush-Pagan 0.000 0.000 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Levin, Lin & Chu 0.001 0.006 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A2 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 4.355*** 11.744*** 4.875*** 4.455*** 11.689*** 4.963*** 11.923*** 11.797*** 11.715*** 11.720*** 12.186*** AR (1) 0.671*** 0.216*** 0.620*** 0.664*** 0.191*** 0.613*** 0.173*** 0.191*** 0.200*** 0.202*** 0.179*** Distance to BRT -0.011 -0.225*** -0.022* -0.017 -0.200*** -0.028* -0.201*** -0.214*** -0.217*** -0.218*** -0.244*** Distance to Prado -0.061*** -0.033 -0.051** -0.062*** -0.020 -0.052** -0.017 -0.023 -0.024 -0.026 -0.025 Estrato Average 0.229*** -0.092* 0.280*** 0.240*** -0.048 0.287*** -0.051 -0.038 -0.052 -0.039 -0.050 Built M2 0.025* 0.000 0.041*** 0.023* -0.008 0.040*** -0.011 -0.007 -0.005 -0.006 -0.006 Type Commercial 0.085 -0.029 -0.042 0.113 0.016 -0.011 -0.014 0.018 0.014 0.008 0.015 Type Residential -0.265*** -0.253*** -0.301*** -0.249*** -0.222*** -0.280*** -0.241*** -0.233*** -0.223*** -0.237*** -0.242*** Stations Soledad 0.082*** -0.008 0.085** 0.083*** 0.010 0.086** -0.006 0.006 0.012 -0.015 0.006 Stations North 0.040 -0.023 0.071** 0.041 0.005 0.069** 0.009 0.004 0.001 -0.006 0.013 D_After -0.021 0.186* -0.019 0.082*** 0.070*** 0.070*** 0.051*** 0.044*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.010 -0.017 0.009 D_2006 0.219 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.044** D_2007 0.078 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.015 D_2008 0.095 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.018 D_2009 -0.367** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.062*** D_2010 0.243 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.021 R2 (adjusted) 0.883 0.915 0.790 0.888 0.919 0.791 0.922 0.918 0.918 0.919 0.922 S.E. of Regression 0.229 0.201 0.232 0.228 0.198 0.231 0.196 0.198 0.198 0.196 0.196 Breush-Pagan 0.270 0.349 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A3 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 13.036*** 97.213 15.921*** 12.539*** 83.919 15.263*** 15.397*** 15.963*** 13.375*** 14.373*** 14.556*** Distance to BRT -0.030 0.084 -0.164*** -0.026 -0.183 -0.249*** -0.373*** -0.260*** -0.297*** -0.295*** -0.314*** Distance to Prado -0.107*** 0.076 -0.277*** -0.093*** -1.501 -0.169* -0.125 -0.233*** -0.027 -0.062 -0.059 Estrato Average 0.554*** -0.453 0.145* 0.554*** -0.294 0.057 0.006 -0.064 -0.054 -0.041 -0.048* Built M2 0.014 -0.027 -0.004 0.014 0.099 -0.007 0.009 -0.012 0.044 -0.006 0.006 Type Commercial 0.360 -1.255 -2.067*** 0.787*** -6.196 -1.428*** -0.846* -1.481*** 0.365 -0.837*** -0.894*** Type Residential -0.879*** -0.873 -0.685*** -0.552*** -0.006 -0.317* 0.021 -0.196 0.587 0.021 -0.049 Stations Soledad 0.149*** -166.206 -0.136 0.135*** -457.200 -0.264* -0.292 -0.283** -0.318** -0.284 -0.476* Stations North 0.284*** 105.172 0.414** 0.287*** -41.293 0.619*** 0.718*** 0.591*** 0.822*** 0.904*** 0.850** D_After 0.433* -0.611 -0.003 0.150** 0.034 0.171*** 0.201*** 0.132*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.043 0.112 0.018 D_2006 -1.155 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) 0.169 D_2007 -0.201 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.073 D_2008 5.456 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.776 D_2009 1.940 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.300 D_2010 -2.279 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.328 R2 (adjusted) 0.773 -25.247 -0.174 0.815 -11.409 -0.102 -0.134 -0.332 -0.726 -0.261 -0.152 S.E. of Regression 0.319 8.684 0.296 0.305 3.248 0.249 0.238 0.270 0.306 0.253 0.231 Hausman 0.993 0.997 0.998 0.996 0.956 1.000 0.999 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 5.038 0.006 2.345 5.630 0.001 0.176 0.096 0.177 0.099 0.044 0.000 Instrument Rank 10 10 10 12 12 12 13 13 13 13 13 P-Value (J-Statistic) 0.025 0.938 0.126 0.018 0.974 0.675 0.757 0.674 0.753 0.834 0.965 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A4 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 0.543 -17.410 7.724*** 0.584 34.097 2.466*** 2.301*** 2.092*** 3.437*** 2.316*** 10.126*** AR (1) 0.957*** 0.445 0.518*** 0.970*** 0.215 0.814*** 0.797*** 0.811*** 0.590*** 0.771*** 0.390*** Distance to BRT -0.021 -0.298 -0.121*** -0.056** -0.328 -0.086*** -0.012 -0.043*** 0.056** -0.009 0.066 Distance to Prado -0.038 0.279 -0.159*** -0.034 -0.715 -0.037*** -0.038* -0.039*** -0.048** -0.036* -0.141*** Estrato Average 0.026 -0.261 0.081*** 0.030 -0.185 0.124*** 0.126** 0.104*** 0.217*** 0.133*** 0.124*** Built M2 0.047** -0.047 0.036*** 0.048** 0.077 0.061*** 0.051*** 0.065*** 0.107*** 0.061*** -0.135*** Type Commercial 0.154 1.261 -0.589*** 0.139 -3.179 0.387*** 0.302 0.581*** 1.241*** 0.613*** -4.223*** Type Residential 0.208 -0.025 -0.020 0.208 0.364 0.242*** 0.144 0.385*** 0.735*** 0.356*** -1.819*** Stations Soledad 0.043 104.565 -0.016 0.043 -139.997 0.042** 0.046* 0.032* 0.035 0.034 -0.166*** Stations North -0.025 31.976 0.141*** -0.031 -10.580 0.001 0.025 0.000 0.041 0.022 0.602*** D_After -0.413* -0.392 -0.525*** 0.043 0.010 0.118*** 0.063*** -0.089** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.063** 0.075 0.084*** D_2006 1.012 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.156 D_2007 0.214 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.003 D_2008 8.439*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -1.207*** D_2009 2.511 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.351 D_2010 19.139*** D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -2.669*** R2 (adjusted) 0.887 0.033 0.311 0.886 0.090 0.728 0.752 0.705 0.326 0.676 -6.031 S.E. of Regression 0.271 1.019 0.238 0.273 1.062 0.268 0.255 0.279 0.421 0.292 0.774 Hausman 0.198 0.266 1.000 0.999 1.000 0.031 1.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 0.260 0.119 0.204 0.255 0.110 0.166 0.995 0.079 0.014 0.091 0.000 Instrument Rank 11 11 11 13 13 13 14 14 14 14 14 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.610 0.730 0.651 0.613 0.740 0.684 0.319 0.779 0.907 0.763 0.998 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A5 Dynamic Panel GMM - First Differences - Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (White Period) GMM 1 GMM 2 GMM 3 GMM 4 GMM 5 GMM 6 GMM 7 AR (1) 0.410*** 0.785*** 0.491*** 0.185*** -0.280*** 0.384*** 0.640*** Distance to BRT -0.414*** -3.323*** -0.104*** -0.228*** -0.689*** -0.419*** -0.303*** Distance to Prado 0.061 -0.232** -0.041 -0.102*** -5.569*** -0.048 0.366*** Estrato Average -2.538*** -1.712*** -0.084** -0.131*** -0.257* -2.246*** -0.528*** Built M2 -0.073*** -0.031** -0.130*** 0.004 -0.343*** -0.168*** -0.157*** Type Commercial -0.378*** -0.951*** -1.379*** 0.143** -1.273*** -0.412*** 0.130 Type Residential -0.189*** 0.162* -0.259*** -0.007 0.668*** -0.152*** 0.032 Stations Soledad -0.246** 0.574*** -0.962*** 0.008 1.524*** -0.160* 3.103*** Stations North -0.051 -0.258* -0.024 -0.010 -4.257*** -0.260*** 0.602*** D_After -25.796*** 0.097*** 0.084*** 0.087*** -0.002 0.016*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 3.649*** D_2006 0.606*** D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.099*** D_2007 -0.477*** D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.069*** D_2008 -1.051*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) 0.131*** D_2009 0.536*** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.064** D_2010 -0.264 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.059 R2 (adjusted) S.E. of Regression 0.517 1.154 0.406 0.289 1.345 0.503 0.481 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 46.646 49.911 53.054 51.411 47.681 47.149 48.584 Instrument Rank 54 56 57 57 57 57 55 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.405 0.284 0.191 0.237 0.364 0.385 0.258 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (WhitePeriod) Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit , show results when using static estimation with and without AR. Fixed Effects (FE) are the best panel effects according to Breusch-Pagan and Haussman tests. In addition, FE specifications always have the highest R2 and the lowest Standard Error. The residuals do not have any spatial autocorrelation, according to the p-value of their Spatial Autoregressive (SAR) parameter.

Figure 7
Simulated Land Prices Time-Series using different static panel estimations

In Tables A1 and A2, Distance to BRT is negative and significant in most of the specifications. Distance to Prado improves in the AR (1) models, as it is negative and significant in all the models. The Period dummy is always positive and significant, but its interaction is not significant in the AR (1) models6 6 We use the AR (1) component to control prices trend. This component performed better than alternative macroeconomic (exogenous) trend controls in our regressions: GDP per capita, Unemployment, and Interest Rate, in accordance to post-Keynesian analyses on the topic (Deleidi, 2018). We must mention that Colombian macroeconomic indicators have been relatively stable (for Latin American standards). Its positive GDP yearly growth rate has been interrupted only three times in the existing records (1929, 1999 and 2020) . The Year dummies and their interactions are not significant in six cases and have non-consistent signs (positive and negative), rejecting the smooth-transition prediction of Neoclassical models.

Figures 7A and 7B are simulations extracted from the regressions (Models FE2 and FE2006 to FE2010). They represent the 10-year evolution of two land price indexes: a) properties in the immediate vicinity of a BRT station, and b) properties located 500 meters away7 7 The selection of the 500 meters buffer does not change any of the regression results, because as explained above, we are using all the available appraisals at the metropolitan scale (a census). We use the buffer only for visualization. . The percentage price difference between those two prices is represented by gray bars in the figures. The effect of Distance to BRT is strong in 2006, decreased during 2007-2009, and increased in 2010. This is evidence in favor of the hypothesis that the markets overreacted at the beginning of the construction in 2006, and cooled down until 2009 due to the construction delays. In order to verify these linear results, we use IV Panel regression in the next section.

4.2. Static Panels: IV Regression with and without AR

The IV panel regressions are reported in Tables A3 and A4 in the Appendix APPENDIX: REGRESSION RESULTS A1 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 13.135*** 14.632*** 13.554*** 12.945*** 14.129*** 13.273*** 14.367*** 14.297*** 14.402*** 14.461*** 14.566*** Distance to BRT -0.060*** -0.234*** -0.092*** -0.045*** -0.192*** -0.071** -0.212*** -0.215*** -0.224*** -0.225*** -0.245*** Distance to Prado -0.171*** -0.061* -0.134*** -0.166*** -0.047 -0.129*** -0.051 -0.050 -0.053 -0.058* -0.053 Estrato Average 0.595*** -0.095* 0.352*** 0.600*** -0.054 0.367*** -0.065 -0.035 -0.061 -0.045 -0.061 Built M2 0.067*** 0.009 0.030** 0.059*** 0.002 0.026* -0.002 0.005 0.007 0.004 0.007 Type Commercial 0.154* -0.034 -0.115 0.210** 0.002 -0.050 -0.033 0.002 -0.005 -0.017 -0.011 Type Residential -0.372*** -0.246*** -0.314*** -0.323*** -0.205*** -0.241*** -0.234*** -0.218*** -0.216*** -0.234*** -0.234*** Stations Soledad 0.159*** 0.056 -0.079 0.157*** 0.066 -0.077 0.054 0.058 0.067 0.052 0.054 Stations North 0.119*** -0.035 0.135*** 0.127*** -0.010 0.142*** -0.015 -0.016 -0.019 -0.027 -0.011 D_After 0.340** 0.314*** 0.360** 0.078*** 0.064*** 0.061*** 0.042*** 0.032** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.041* -0.037** -0.041* D_2006 0.174 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.040* D_2007 0.297* D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.047* D_2008 0.232 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.038 D_2009 -0.244 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.045* D_2010 0.150 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.006 R2 (adjusted) 0.770 0.892 0.251 0.774 0.897 0.273 0.901 0.897 0.896 0.897 0.902 S.E. of Regression 0.288 0.203 0.222 0.287 0.201 0.220 0.199 0.201 0.201 0.200 0.200 Breush-Pagan 0.000 0.000 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Levin, Lin & Chu 0.001 0.006 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A2 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 4.355*** 11.744*** 4.875*** 4.455*** 11.689*** 4.963*** 11.923*** 11.797*** 11.715*** 11.720*** 12.186*** AR (1) 0.671*** 0.216*** 0.620*** 0.664*** 0.191*** 0.613*** 0.173*** 0.191*** 0.200*** 0.202*** 0.179*** Distance to BRT -0.011 -0.225*** -0.022* -0.017 -0.200*** -0.028* -0.201*** -0.214*** -0.217*** -0.218*** -0.244*** Distance to Prado -0.061*** -0.033 -0.051** -0.062*** -0.020 -0.052** -0.017 -0.023 -0.024 -0.026 -0.025 Estrato Average 0.229*** -0.092* 0.280*** 0.240*** -0.048 0.287*** -0.051 -0.038 -0.052 -0.039 -0.050 Built M2 0.025* 0.000 0.041*** 0.023* -0.008 0.040*** -0.011 -0.007 -0.005 -0.006 -0.006 Type Commercial 0.085 -0.029 -0.042 0.113 0.016 -0.011 -0.014 0.018 0.014 0.008 0.015 Type Residential -0.265*** -0.253*** -0.301*** -0.249*** -0.222*** -0.280*** -0.241*** -0.233*** -0.223*** -0.237*** -0.242*** Stations Soledad 0.082*** -0.008 0.085** 0.083*** 0.010 0.086** -0.006 0.006 0.012 -0.015 0.006 Stations North 0.040 -0.023 0.071** 0.041 0.005 0.069** 0.009 0.004 0.001 -0.006 0.013 D_After -0.021 0.186* -0.019 0.082*** 0.070*** 0.070*** 0.051*** 0.044*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.010 -0.017 0.009 D_2006 0.219 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.044** D_2007 0.078 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.015 D_2008 0.095 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.018 D_2009 -0.367** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.062*** D_2010 0.243 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.021 R2 (adjusted) 0.883 0.915 0.790 0.888 0.919 0.791 0.922 0.918 0.918 0.919 0.922 S.E. of Regression 0.229 0.201 0.232 0.228 0.198 0.231 0.196 0.198 0.198 0.196 0.196 Breush-Pagan 0.270 0.349 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A3 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 13.036*** 97.213 15.921*** 12.539*** 83.919 15.263*** 15.397*** 15.963*** 13.375*** 14.373*** 14.556*** Distance to BRT -0.030 0.084 -0.164*** -0.026 -0.183 -0.249*** -0.373*** -0.260*** -0.297*** -0.295*** -0.314*** Distance to Prado -0.107*** 0.076 -0.277*** -0.093*** -1.501 -0.169* -0.125 -0.233*** -0.027 -0.062 -0.059 Estrato Average 0.554*** -0.453 0.145* 0.554*** -0.294 0.057 0.006 -0.064 -0.054 -0.041 -0.048* Built M2 0.014 -0.027 -0.004 0.014 0.099 -0.007 0.009 -0.012 0.044 -0.006 0.006 Type Commercial 0.360 -1.255 -2.067*** 0.787*** -6.196 -1.428*** -0.846* -1.481*** 0.365 -0.837*** -0.894*** Type Residential -0.879*** -0.873 -0.685*** -0.552*** -0.006 -0.317* 0.021 -0.196 0.587 0.021 -0.049 Stations Soledad 0.149*** -166.206 -0.136 0.135*** -457.200 -0.264* -0.292 -0.283** -0.318** -0.284 -0.476* Stations North 0.284*** 105.172 0.414** 0.287*** -41.293 0.619*** 0.718*** 0.591*** 0.822*** 0.904*** 0.850** D_After 0.433* -0.611 -0.003 0.150** 0.034 0.171*** 0.201*** 0.132*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.043 0.112 0.018 D_2006 -1.155 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) 0.169 D_2007 -0.201 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.073 D_2008 5.456 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.776 D_2009 1.940 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.300 D_2010 -2.279 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.328 R2 (adjusted) 0.773 -25.247 -0.174 0.815 -11.409 -0.102 -0.134 -0.332 -0.726 -0.261 -0.152 S.E. of Regression 0.319 8.684 0.296 0.305 3.248 0.249 0.238 0.270 0.306 0.253 0.231 Hausman 0.993 0.997 0.998 0.996 0.956 1.000 0.999 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 5.038 0.006 2.345 5.630 0.001 0.176 0.096 0.177 0.099 0.044 0.000 Instrument Rank 10 10 10 12 12 12 13 13 13 13 13 P-Value (J-Statistic) 0.025 0.938 0.126 0.018 0.974 0.675 0.757 0.674 0.753 0.834 0.965 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A4 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 0.543 -17.410 7.724*** 0.584 34.097 2.466*** 2.301*** 2.092*** 3.437*** 2.316*** 10.126*** AR (1) 0.957*** 0.445 0.518*** 0.970*** 0.215 0.814*** 0.797*** 0.811*** 0.590*** 0.771*** 0.390*** Distance to BRT -0.021 -0.298 -0.121*** -0.056** -0.328 -0.086*** -0.012 -0.043*** 0.056** -0.009 0.066 Distance to Prado -0.038 0.279 -0.159*** -0.034 -0.715 -0.037*** -0.038* -0.039*** -0.048** -0.036* -0.141*** Estrato Average 0.026 -0.261 0.081*** 0.030 -0.185 0.124*** 0.126** 0.104*** 0.217*** 0.133*** 0.124*** Built M2 0.047** -0.047 0.036*** 0.048** 0.077 0.061*** 0.051*** 0.065*** 0.107*** 0.061*** -0.135*** Type Commercial 0.154 1.261 -0.589*** 0.139 -3.179 0.387*** 0.302 0.581*** 1.241*** 0.613*** -4.223*** Type Residential 0.208 -0.025 -0.020 0.208 0.364 0.242*** 0.144 0.385*** 0.735*** 0.356*** -1.819*** Stations Soledad 0.043 104.565 -0.016 0.043 -139.997 0.042** 0.046* 0.032* 0.035 0.034 -0.166*** Stations North -0.025 31.976 0.141*** -0.031 -10.580 0.001 0.025 0.000 0.041 0.022 0.602*** D_After -0.413* -0.392 -0.525*** 0.043 0.010 0.118*** 0.063*** -0.089** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.063** 0.075 0.084*** D_2006 1.012 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.156 D_2007 0.214 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.003 D_2008 8.439*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -1.207*** D_2009 2.511 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.351 D_2010 19.139*** D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -2.669*** R2 (adjusted) 0.887 0.033 0.311 0.886 0.090 0.728 0.752 0.705 0.326 0.676 -6.031 S.E. of Regression 0.271 1.019 0.238 0.273 1.062 0.268 0.255 0.279 0.421 0.292 0.774 Hausman 0.198 0.266 1.000 0.999 1.000 0.031 1.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 0.260 0.119 0.204 0.255 0.110 0.166 0.995 0.079 0.014 0.091 0.000 Instrument Rank 11 11 11 13 13 13 14 14 14 14 14 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.610 0.730 0.651 0.613 0.740 0.684 0.319 0.779 0.907 0.763 0.998 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A5 Dynamic Panel GMM - First Differences - Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (White Period) GMM 1 GMM 2 GMM 3 GMM 4 GMM 5 GMM 6 GMM 7 AR (1) 0.410*** 0.785*** 0.491*** 0.185*** -0.280*** 0.384*** 0.640*** Distance to BRT -0.414*** -3.323*** -0.104*** -0.228*** -0.689*** -0.419*** -0.303*** Distance to Prado 0.061 -0.232** -0.041 -0.102*** -5.569*** -0.048 0.366*** Estrato Average -2.538*** -1.712*** -0.084** -0.131*** -0.257* -2.246*** -0.528*** Built M2 -0.073*** -0.031** -0.130*** 0.004 -0.343*** -0.168*** -0.157*** Type Commercial -0.378*** -0.951*** -1.379*** 0.143** -1.273*** -0.412*** 0.130 Type Residential -0.189*** 0.162* -0.259*** -0.007 0.668*** -0.152*** 0.032 Stations Soledad -0.246** 0.574*** -0.962*** 0.008 1.524*** -0.160* 3.103*** Stations North -0.051 -0.258* -0.024 -0.010 -4.257*** -0.260*** 0.602*** D_After -25.796*** 0.097*** 0.084*** 0.087*** -0.002 0.016*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 3.649*** D_2006 0.606*** D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.099*** D_2007 -0.477*** D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.069*** D_2008 -1.051*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) 0.131*** D_2009 0.536*** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.064** D_2010 -0.264 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.059 R2 (adjusted) S.E. of Regression 0.517 1.154 0.406 0.289 1.345 0.503 0.481 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 46.646 49.911 53.054 51.411 47.681 47.149 48.584 Instrument Rank 54 56 57 57 57 57 55 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.405 0.284 0.191 0.237 0.364 0.385 0.258 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (WhitePeriod) Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit , and in Figures 7C and 7D. The instruments are consistent in all the regressions, according to the J-Statistic8 8 The list of instruments is at the bottom of the tables. . RE is the best specification according to the Haussman test. All the errors clear panel unit-root according to Levin, Lin & Chu, and do not have spatial autocorrelation. The effect of Distance to BRT is negative, although it is not significant in many specifications. Distance to Prado is always negative and significant. The Period dummy has non-consistent changes of the sign. Its interaction with Distance to BRT is positive and significant, while the dummies per years and their interactions have changing signs. These results confirm the linear regressions and further reject the Neoclassical smooth-transition prediction.

All the panels in Figure 7 depict the overreaction to the TransMetro construction in 2006, and its fluctuating adjustment. We would be willing to accept the Neoclassical smooth-transition interpretation if the short-term adjustments were in the same direction (consistent signs). However, the parameter is fluctuating, as predicted by post-Keynesian Monetary Circuit theory.

4.3 Dynamic Panel: Arellano-Bond GMM

Figure 8 and Table A5 in the Appendix APPENDIX: REGRESSION RESULTS A1 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 13.135*** 14.632*** 13.554*** 12.945*** 14.129*** 13.273*** 14.367*** 14.297*** 14.402*** 14.461*** 14.566*** Distance to BRT -0.060*** -0.234*** -0.092*** -0.045*** -0.192*** -0.071** -0.212*** -0.215*** -0.224*** -0.225*** -0.245*** Distance to Prado -0.171*** -0.061* -0.134*** -0.166*** -0.047 -0.129*** -0.051 -0.050 -0.053 -0.058* -0.053 Estrato Average 0.595*** -0.095* 0.352*** 0.600*** -0.054 0.367*** -0.065 -0.035 -0.061 -0.045 -0.061 Built M2 0.067*** 0.009 0.030** 0.059*** 0.002 0.026* -0.002 0.005 0.007 0.004 0.007 Type Commercial 0.154* -0.034 -0.115 0.210** 0.002 -0.050 -0.033 0.002 -0.005 -0.017 -0.011 Type Residential -0.372*** -0.246*** -0.314*** -0.323*** -0.205*** -0.241*** -0.234*** -0.218*** -0.216*** -0.234*** -0.234*** Stations Soledad 0.159*** 0.056 -0.079 0.157*** 0.066 -0.077 0.054 0.058 0.067 0.052 0.054 Stations North 0.119*** -0.035 0.135*** 0.127*** -0.010 0.142*** -0.015 -0.016 -0.019 -0.027 -0.011 D_After 0.340** 0.314*** 0.360** 0.078*** 0.064*** 0.061*** 0.042*** 0.032** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.041* -0.037** -0.041* D_2006 0.174 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.040* D_2007 0.297* D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.047* D_2008 0.232 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.038 D_2009 -0.244 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.045* D_2010 0.150 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.006 R2 (adjusted) 0.770 0.892 0.251 0.774 0.897 0.273 0.901 0.897 0.896 0.897 0.902 S.E. of Regression 0.288 0.203 0.222 0.287 0.201 0.220 0.199 0.201 0.201 0.200 0.200 Breush-Pagan 0.000 0.000 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Levin, Lin & Chu 0.001 0.006 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 682 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A2 Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE FE FE FE FE FE Constant 4.355*** 11.744*** 4.875*** 4.455*** 11.689*** 4.963*** 11.923*** 11.797*** 11.715*** 11.720*** 12.186*** AR (1) 0.671*** 0.216*** 0.620*** 0.664*** 0.191*** 0.613*** 0.173*** 0.191*** 0.200*** 0.202*** 0.179*** Distance to BRT -0.011 -0.225*** -0.022* -0.017 -0.200*** -0.028* -0.201*** -0.214*** -0.217*** -0.218*** -0.244*** Distance to Prado -0.061*** -0.033 -0.051** -0.062*** -0.020 -0.052** -0.017 -0.023 -0.024 -0.026 -0.025 Estrato Average 0.229*** -0.092* 0.280*** 0.240*** -0.048 0.287*** -0.051 -0.038 -0.052 -0.039 -0.050 Built M2 0.025* 0.000 0.041*** 0.023* -0.008 0.040*** -0.011 -0.007 -0.005 -0.006 -0.006 Type Commercial 0.085 -0.029 -0.042 0.113 0.016 -0.011 -0.014 0.018 0.014 0.008 0.015 Type Residential -0.265*** -0.253*** -0.301*** -0.249*** -0.222*** -0.280*** -0.241*** -0.233*** -0.223*** -0.237*** -0.242*** Stations Soledad 0.082*** -0.008 0.085** 0.083*** 0.010 0.086** -0.006 0.006 0.012 -0.015 0.006 Stations North 0.040 -0.023 0.071** 0.041 0.005 0.069** 0.009 0.004 0.001 -0.006 0.013 D_After -0.021 0.186* -0.019 0.082*** 0.070*** 0.070*** 0.051*** 0.044*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.010 -0.017 0.009 D_2006 0.219 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.044** D_2007 0.078 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.015 D_2008 0.095 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.018 D_2009 -0.367** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) 0.062*** D_2010 0.243 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -0.021 R2 (adjusted) 0.883 0.915 0.790 0.888 0.919 0.791 0.922 0.918 0.918 0.919 0.922 S.E. of Regression 0.229 0.201 0.232 0.228 0.198 0.231 0.196 0.198 0.198 0.196 0.196 Breush-Pagan 0.270 0.349 Redundant Fixed Effects 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Hausman Random Effects 0.000 0.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Observations 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 620 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A3 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 13.036*** 97.213 15.921*** 12.539*** 83.919 15.263*** 15.397*** 15.963*** 13.375*** 14.373*** 14.556*** Distance to BRT -0.030 0.084 -0.164*** -0.026 -0.183 -0.249*** -0.373*** -0.260*** -0.297*** -0.295*** -0.314*** Distance to Prado -0.107*** 0.076 -0.277*** -0.093*** -1.501 -0.169* -0.125 -0.233*** -0.027 -0.062 -0.059 Estrato Average 0.554*** -0.453 0.145* 0.554*** -0.294 0.057 0.006 -0.064 -0.054 -0.041 -0.048* Built M2 0.014 -0.027 -0.004 0.014 0.099 -0.007 0.009 -0.012 0.044 -0.006 0.006 Type Commercial 0.360 -1.255 -2.067*** 0.787*** -6.196 -1.428*** -0.846* -1.481*** 0.365 -0.837*** -0.894*** Type Residential -0.879*** -0.873 -0.685*** -0.552*** -0.006 -0.317* 0.021 -0.196 0.587 0.021 -0.049 Stations Soledad 0.149*** -166.206 -0.136 0.135*** -457.200 -0.264* -0.292 -0.283** -0.318** -0.284 -0.476* Stations North 0.284*** 105.172 0.414** 0.287*** -41.293 0.619*** 0.718*** 0.591*** 0.822*** 0.904*** 0.850** D_After 0.433* -0.611 -0.003 0.150** 0.034 0.171*** 0.201*** 0.132*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) -0.043 0.112 0.018 D_2006 -1.155 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) 0.169 D_2007 -0.201 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.073 D_2008 5.456 D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -0.776 D_2009 1.940 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.300 D_2010 -2.279 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.328 R2 (adjusted) 0.773 -25.247 -0.174 0.815 -11.409 -0.102 -0.134 -0.332 -0.726 -0.261 -0.152 S.E. of Regression 0.319 8.684 0.296 0.305 3.248 0.249 0.238 0.270 0.306 0.253 0.231 Hausman 0.993 0.997 0.998 0.996 0.956 1.000 0.999 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 5.038 0.006 2.345 5.630 0.001 0.176 0.096 0.177 0.099 0.044 0.000 Instrument Rank 10 10 10 12 12 12 13 13 13 13 13 P-Value (J-Statistic) 0.025 0.938 0.126 0.018 0.974 0.675 0.757 0.674 0.753 0.834 0.965 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A4 I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1) Pooling FE RE Pooling FE RE RE RE RE RE RE Constant 0.543 -17.410 7.724*** 0.584 34.097 2.466*** 2.301*** 2.092*** 3.437*** 2.316*** 10.126*** AR (1) 0.957*** 0.445 0.518*** 0.970*** 0.215 0.814*** 0.797*** 0.811*** 0.590*** 0.771*** 0.390*** Distance to BRT -0.021 -0.298 -0.121*** -0.056** -0.328 -0.086*** -0.012 -0.043*** 0.056** -0.009 0.066 Distance to Prado -0.038 0.279 -0.159*** -0.034 -0.715 -0.037*** -0.038* -0.039*** -0.048** -0.036* -0.141*** Estrato Average 0.026 -0.261 0.081*** 0.030 -0.185 0.124*** 0.126** 0.104*** 0.217*** 0.133*** 0.124*** Built M2 0.047** -0.047 0.036*** 0.048** 0.077 0.061*** 0.051*** 0.065*** 0.107*** 0.061*** -0.135*** Type Commercial 0.154 1.261 -0.589*** 0.139 -3.179 0.387*** 0.302 0.581*** 1.241*** 0.613*** -4.223*** Type Residential 0.208 -0.025 -0.020 0.208 0.364 0.242*** 0.144 0.385*** 0.735*** 0.356*** -1.819*** Stations Soledad 0.043 104.565 -0.016 0.043 -139.997 0.042** 0.046* 0.032* 0.035 0.034 -0.166*** Stations North -0.025 31.976 0.141*** -0.031 -10.580 0.001 0.025 0.000 0.041 0.022 0.602*** D_After -0.413* -0.392 -0.525*** 0.043 0.010 0.118*** 0.063*** -0.089** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 0.063** 0.075 0.084*** D_2006 1.012 D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.156 D_2007 0.214 D_2007* (Distance to BRT) -0.003 D_2008 8.439*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) -1.207*** D_2009 2.511 D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.351 D_2010 19.139*** D_2010* (Distance to BRT) -2.669*** R2 (adjusted) 0.887 0.033 0.311 0.886 0.090 0.728 0.752 0.705 0.326 0.676 -6.031 S.E. of Regression 0.271 1.019 0.238 0.273 1.062 0.268 0.255 0.279 0.421 0.292 0.774 Hausman 0.198 0.266 1.000 0.999 1.000 0.031 1.000 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 0.260 0.119 0.204 0.255 0.110 0.166 0.995 0.079 0.014 0.091 0.000 Instrument Rank 11 11 11 13 13 13 14 14 14 14 14 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.610 0.730 0.651 0.613 0.740 0.684 0.319 0.779 0.907 0.763 0.998 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit A5 Dynamic Panel GMM - First Differences - Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (White Period) GMM 1 GMM 2 GMM 3 GMM 4 GMM 5 GMM 6 GMM 7 AR (1) 0.410*** 0.785*** 0.491*** 0.185*** -0.280*** 0.384*** 0.640*** Distance to BRT -0.414*** -3.323*** -0.104*** -0.228*** -0.689*** -0.419*** -0.303*** Distance to Prado 0.061 -0.232** -0.041 -0.102*** -5.569*** -0.048 0.366*** Estrato Average -2.538*** -1.712*** -0.084** -0.131*** -0.257* -2.246*** -0.528*** Built M2 -0.073*** -0.031** -0.130*** 0.004 -0.343*** -0.168*** -0.157*** Type Commercial -0.378*** -0.951*** -1.379*** 0.143** -1.273*** -0.412*** 0.130 Type Residential -0.189*** 0.162* -0.259*** -0.007 0.668*** -0.152*** 0.032 Stations Soledad -0.246** 0.574*** -0.962*** 0.008 1.524*** -0.160* 3.103*** Stations North -0.051 -0.258* -0.024 -0.010 -4.257*** -0.260*** 0.602*** D_After -25.796*** 0.097*** 0.084*** 0.087*** -0.002 0.016*** D_After* (Distance to BRT) 3.649*** D_2006 0.606*** D_2006* (Distance to BRT) -0.099*** D_2007 -0.477*** D_2007* (Distance to BRT) 0.069*** D_2008 -1.051*** D_2008* (Distance to BRT) 0.131*** D_2009 0.536*** D_2009* (Distance to BRT) -0.064** D_2010 -0.264 D_2010* (Distance to BRT) 0.059 R2 (adjusted) S.E. of Regression 0.517 1.154 0.406 0.289 1.345 0.503 0.481 Unit Root 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 J-Statistic 46.646 49.911 53.054 51.411 47.681 47.149 48.584 Instrument Rank 54 56 57 57 57 57 55 P-value (J-Statistic) 0.405 0.284 0.191 0.237 0.364 0.385 0.258 Observations 558 558 558 558 558 558 558 ***Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; *Significant at 10% After=dummy variable for 2006 - 2010; Year=dummy variable for the corresponding year in the specification Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (WhitePeriod) Controls=Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North. All the variables introduced as logarithms, except the dummies or percentages Instruments: AR (1) of Distance to Prado; Estrato Average; Built M2; L and M2; Type Commercial; Type Residential; Stations Soledad; Stations North; and of the After, After·Distance to BRT, Year and Year·Distance to BRT dummies 1. H0: Redundant Panel Effects; 2. H0: Fixed Effects are redundant; 3. H0: Random Effects are not correlated with the X variables; 4: H0: There is Unit Root in the residuals; 5. H0: IV estimation is not overidentified; 5. p-value of the Panel Spatial Autorregresive parameter: μit=2WNTμit+uit show dynamic panel results. All the models have correctly specified instruments (variables lagged) according to the J-Statistic, and their residuals have cleared unit-root according to Levin, Lin & Chu. The differentiation has made the panel effects redundant while eliminating spatial autocorrelation. The AR (1) is always significant, and has negative sign in 20089 9 A land prices growth deceleration (not decrease) due to an exogenous shock: the US sub-prime crisis. . Distance to BRT is always significant and negative. Period dummy is always significant, except in GMM2009, and its interaction in GMM2 is positive. Year dummies and their interactions are significant in all the models, except GMM2010.

Figure 8
Simulated Land Prices Time-Series using Dynamic Panel estimation

Figure 8 simulates the estimated growth rates for hypothetical properties


Figure 8 simulates the estimated growth rates for hypothetical properties in the immediate vicinity of a BRT station, at 500 meters, and the city-wide average. Prices at the BRT and at 500 meters away grew faster than the city-wide average before the announcement and construction of the BRT (2002 to 2004). During construction and delivery, the graph portrays fluctuations that reject the Neoclassical smooth-transition prediction: lower prices in 2006 and 2007, higher in 2008 and 2009, and decreasing again in 2010.

Distance to Prado in Table A5 is consistently negative, but not significant in all the specifications. Therefore, it even rejects the baseline city-wide model (Figure 3). This is a situation akin to the radical uncertainty depicted in Figure 2, where even well-informed market agents (appraisers) cannot determine the long-run trends.

5. CONCLUSIONS

Transport infrastructure construction, including BRT systems, tends to have positive long-run effects on land prices. However, the short-term effects have been less analyzed because Neoclassical urban economics underlies most of the research in the field, implicitly taking the role of transport engineering or transport geography. In Neoclassical general equilibrium the short-term adjustments are merely intermediate steps toward long-run convergence, and uncertainty is limited: city-wide land price spatial structures smoothly converge to long-run trends by zones and uses.

To illuminate the existence of radical uncertainty we use Monetary Circuit, a post-Keynesian theory where money is endogenous to the economy and subject to uncertain institutional arrangements. These conditions result in uncertain arrangements among developers-financiers-government in the urban monetary sub-circuits. There is radical uncertainty because market agents cannot set on the spatial distribution of land prices in the long-term. Radical uncertainty causes lack of development, urban informality, and poor-quality built environment (Abramo, 2020Abramo, P. (2020), The comp-fuse city: informal land market and urban structure in Latin American metropolises. In: Van den Broeck, P. et al. (eds), Communities, Land and Social Innovation: Land Taking and Land Making in an Urbanising World. Edward Elgar Publishing Inc. Northampton, MA, USA.).

We test radical uncertainty using dynamic and non-dynamic panel DiD regression in Barranquilla (Colombia), during the period 2000-2010. This metropolitan area offers an ideal case study because of the uncertainty introduced into the city-wide land price market because of delays in the construction of Transmetro, its BRT system. We verify that its short-term land price adjustments do not converge to a predictable spatial-temporal adjustment pattern, as there is inconsistency in signs across years. In addition, the city-wide spatial land market had inconsistent parameters. We conclude that market agents, even well-informed ones like property appraisers, cannot identify the long-run land price trends. In other words, market agents are exposed to radical uncertainty, as predicted by the Monetary Circuit theory applied to urban economics.

That it is nearly impossible to forecast prices per city zone comes as no surprise to practitioners. The predictions change with the availability of information, the progress of public works projects, and ongoing urban development. A practical implication of this observation is that government assessors cannot accurately determine ex-ante land value exactions; they can only do it ex-post. It is fairer and more efficient to develop urban infrastructure using government debt and charge the land value increases only after the long-run city-wide spatial distribution is clear (long-run trends settled), using either land exactions or property taxes.

Urban radical uncertainty causes more than forecasting challenges, it illuminates the impacts that the weakness of the institutional arrangements can have on urban development in the long-run. Because of radical uncertainty, models based upon long-run Neoclassical general equilibrium, even in its implicit forms, are misleading conceptual frameworks for urban economics research in the Global South.

We must clarify that we are not discussing the validity of using the Neoclassical approach to describe the static spatial structure of urban land uses and prices. In fact, we use it as our baseline estimation model. What we argue is that its static conceptual properties cannot simply be extrapolated to its spatial adjustment dynamics, which include normative propositions as urban development guidelines. Alternative conceptual approaches to urban economics research are needed.

REFERENCES

  • Abramo, P. (2011). La Ciudad Caleidoscópica, Coordinación Espacial y Convención Urbana: una Perspectiva Heterodoxa para la Economía Urbana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 4 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota.
  • Abramo, P. (2020), The comp-fuse city: informal land market and urban structure in Latin American metropolises. In: Van den Broeck, P. et al. (eds), Communities, Land and Social Innovation: Land Taking and Land Making in an Urbanising World. Edward Elgar Publishing Inc. Northampton, MA, USA.
  • Aglietta, M. & J. Cartelier (2002), Orden monetario de las economías de mercado. Cuadernos de Economía 21(36), 41-75
  • Alfonso, O. (2007), Aportes a una teoría de la estructuración residencial urbana. Revista de Economía Institucional 9(17), 241-277
  • Alfonso, O. (2009), Metropolítica: un análisis de algunas experiencias metropolitanas globales. Cadernos Metropole, 21(1), 53-74.
  • Alfonso, O. (2017), Bogotá en la Encrucijada del Desorden: Estructuras Socioespaciales y Gobernabilidad Metropolitana. Colección Economía Institucional Urbana 13 - Universidad Externado de Colombia, Bogota .
  • Almeida, R. & R. Monte-Mor (2017), Renda da terra e o espaço urbano capitalista contemporâneo. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 37(2), 417-436.
  • Arellana, J.; D. Oviedo, L. Guzman & V. Alvarez (2021), Urban transport planning and access inequalities: A tale of two Colombian cities. Research in Transportation Business & Management, 40, 100554.
  • Bao Nguyen, T.; E. Van de Krabben & D. Samsura (2017), A curious case of property privatization: two examples of the tragedy of the anticommons in Ho Chi Minh City-Vietnam. International Journal of Urban Sciences 21(1), 72-90.
  • Cesaratto, S. (2017), Initial and final finance in the monetary circuit and the theory of effective demand. Metroeconomica 68(2), 228-258.
  • Cirolia, L. & S. Berrisford (2017), ‘Negotiated planning’: Diverse trajectories of implementation in Nairobi, Addis Ababa, and Harare. Habitat International 59, 71-79
  • Combs, T. (2017), Examining changes in travel patterns among lower wealth households after BRT investment in Bogotá, Colombia. Journal of Transport Geography 60, 11-20
  • Deleidi, M. (2018), Post Keynesian endogenous money theory: A theoretical and empirical investigation of the credit demand schedule. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, 41(2), 185-209
  • Deleidi, M. & G. Fontana (2019), Money Creation in the Eurozone: An Empirical Assessment of the Endogenous and the Exogenous Money Theories. Review of Political Economy 31:4, 559-581
  • Devaux, N., Dubé, J., & Apparicio, P. (2017), Anticipation and post-construction impact of a metro extension on residential values: the case of Laval (Canada), 1995-2013. Journal of Transport Geography 67, 8-19.
  • Dubé, J., Legros, D., & Devaux, N. (2018). From bus to tramway: Is there an economic impact of substituting a rapid mass transit system? An empirical investigation accounting for anticipation effect. Transportation Research Part A 110, 73-87.
  • El Heraldo (2011), A la política le cogí verdadero miedo: Guillermo Hoenigsberg, 03/Agosto/2011. https://www.elheraldo.co/judicial/a-la-pol-tica-le-cog­-verdadero­­-miedo­-guillermo-hoenigsberg-32014
    » https://www.elheraldo.co/judicial/a-la-pol-tica-le-cog­-verdadero­­-miedo­-guillermo-hoenigsberg-32014
  • Fratianni, M. & F. Spinelli (2006), Italian city-states and financial evolution. European Review of Economic History 10(3), 257-278
  • Garza, N. (2019), Spatial and dynamic features of land value capture, a case study from Bogota, Colombia. Public Finance Review 47(3), 603-622
  • Garza, N. & C. Lizieri (2019), An empirical approach to land monopoly: A case study of the city of Barranquilla, Colombia. Urban Studies, 56(10), 1931-1950
  • Higgins, C. D., & Kanaroglou, P. S. (2016). Forty years of modelling rapid transit’s land value uplift in North America: Moving beyond the tip of the iceberg. Transport Reviews, 36(5), 610-634.
  • Jaramillo, C.; C. Lizárraga & A. Grindlay (2012), Spatial disparity in transport social needs and public transport provision in Santiago de Cali (Colombia). Journal of Transport Geography 24, 340-357
  • La Silla Vacía (2010), La Mala Hora de Alex Char, 21/11/2010. https://lasillavacia.com/historia/19978
    » https://lasillavacia.com/historia/19978
  • Lizieri, C. & S. Satchell (1997), Interactions between property and equity markets: an investigation of linkages in the United Kingdom 1972-1992. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 15(1), 11-26.
  • Loasby, B. (2011), Uncertainty and imagination, illusion and order: Shackleian connections. Cambridge Journal of Economics 35(4), 771-783.
  • Mathur, S. (2019), An evaluative framework for examining the use of land value capture to fund public transportation projects. Land Use Policy 86, 357-364.
  • Mesthrige, W.; T Ip Lam & M. Lai Chong (2015), The impact of anticipated transport improvement on property prices: A case study in Hong Kong. Habitat International 49, 148-156.
  • Mohammad, S. I., Graham, D. J., Melo, P. C., & Anderson, R. J. (2013). A Meta-analysis of the impact of rail projects on land and property values. Transportation Research Part A, 50, 158-170.
  • Palley, T. (2017), The theory of endogenous money and the LM schedule: prelude to a reconstruction of IS-LM. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 37(1), 3-22.
  • Park, J. (2014), Land rent theory revisited. Science & Society, 78(1), 88-109.
  • Payares, D. (2012), Estimación del potencial de valorización del suelo en Barranquilla en el periodo 2001-2011: Estimación de efectos fijos en datos de panel. Revista de Economía del Caribe 10, 65-91.
  • Penido, M. (1999), Moeda endógena e passividade bancária: uma análise crítica da abordagem. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 19(4), 114-133.
  • Perez-Valbuena, G.; J. Ayala-Garcia & E. Chirivi-Bonilla (2016), Urbanización y compromiso comunitario: cinco estudios de caso sobre infraestructura social en educación y salud. Revista de Economía del Caribe 18, 140-159
  • Portafolio (2010), Prende motores el Transmetro de Barranquilla, 06/04/2010. https://www.portafolio.co/economia/finanzas/prende-motores-transmetro-barranquilla-374332
    » https://www.portafolio.co/economia/finanzas/prende-motores-transmetro-barranquilla-374332
  • Semana (2006), Romance Caribe, 5/19/2006. https://www.semana.com/on-line/articulo/romance-caribe/78949-3
    » https://www.semana.com/on-line/articulo/romance-caribe/78949-3
  • Von Mettenheim, K. (2006), Still the Century of Government Savings Banks? The Caixa Econômica Federal. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 26(1), 39-57
  • Wang, Y., et al. (2015), Bus stop, property price and land value tax: A multilevel hedonic analysis with quantile calibration. Land Use Policy 42, 381-391.
  • Yen, B. et al. (2018), Announcement, construction or delivery: when does value uplift occur for residential properties? Evidence from the Gold Coast Light Rail system in Australia. Land Use Policy 73, 412-422
  • 1
    Literature on the interactions between transport and real estate customarily uses pre-determined buffers of impact in data collection and estimation. That is, quasi-experimental research designs that dismiss analyses at the city-wide scale.
  • 2
    The expected and obtained signs for these parameters are discussed in section 4.
  • 3
    Recent contributions by Devaux et al. (2017Devaux, N., Dubé, J., & Apparicio, P. (2017), Anticipation and post-construction impact of a metro extension on residential values: the case of Laval (Canada), 1995-2013. Journal of Transport Geography 67, 8-19.) and Dubé et al. (2018Dubé, J., Legros, D., & Devaux, N. (2018). From bus to tramway: Is there an economic impact of substituting a rapid mass transit system? An empirical investigation accounting for anticipation effect. Transportation Research Part A 110, 73-87.), detect similar fluctuations in their city gradient and Distance to BRT parameters. However, they do not discuss the underlying theoretical model, emphasizing the technical spatial analysis details instead.
  • 4
    In recent years Barranquilla, although not Soledad, has improved its indicators of institutional performance, increasing property tax collection and revenue administration efficiency.
  • 5
    We must clarify that Colombian Lonjas are private but regulated institutions, and appraisals can be legally and technically challenged. Property Valuation is a relatively established and trustworthy professional activity. Lonja de Barranquilla uses the database to produce its yearly land prices reports, and to support its department of technical analysis and valuation (Payares, 2012Payares, D. (2012), Estimación del potencial de valorización del suelo en Barranquilla en el periodo 2001-2011: Estimación de efectos fijos en datos de panel. Revista de Economía del Caribe 10, 65-91.).
  • 6
    We use the AR (1) component to control prices trend. This component performed better than alternative macroeconomic (exogenous) trend controls in our regressions: GDP per capita, Unemployment, and Interest Rate, in accordance to post-Keynesian analyses on the topic (Deleidi, 2018Deleidi, M. (2018), Post Keynesian endogenous money theory: A theoretical and empirical investigation of the credit demand schedule. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, 41(2), 185-209). We must mention that Colombian macroeconomic indicators have been relatively stable (for Latin American standards). Its positive GDP yearly growth rate has been interrupted only three times in the existing records (1929, 1999 and 2020)
  • 7
    The selection of the 500 meters buffer does not change any of the regression results, because as explained above, we are using all the available appraisals at the metropolitan scale (a census). We use the buffer only for visualization.
  • 8
    The list of instruments is at the bottom of the tables.
  • 9
    A land prices growth deceleration (not decrease) due to an exogenous shock: the US sub-prime crisis.
  • 10
    JEL Classification: B41; B52; E12; R30.

APPENDIX: REGRESSION RESULTS

A1
Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1)
A2
Linear Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1)
A3
I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - no AR (1)
A4
I.V. Regression - pooling, F.E. and R.E. - Cross-section Weights - with AR (1)
A5
Dynamic Panel GMM - First Differences - Arellano-Bond Dynamic Instruments - White Period Instrument Weighting Matrix - Robust Errors (White Period)

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    07 Aug 2023
  • Date of issue
    Jul-Sep 2023

History

  • Received
    19 Aug 2021
  • Accepted
    13 Dec 2022
Centro de Economia Política Rua Araripina, 106, CEP 05603-030 São Paulo - SP, Tel. (55 11) 3816-6053 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: cecilia.heise@bjpe.org.br