Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Consumption-Wealth Ratio and Expected Stock Returns: Evidence from Panel Data on G7 Countries* * We are especially grateful for the comments and suggestions given by Wagner Gaglianone, Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira, Ricardo Sousa and other seminar participants at the 2nd International Workshop on "Financial Markets and Nonlinear Dynamics" (FMND) in Paris. Any remaining errors are ours. Both Castro and Issler gratefully acknowledge the support from CNPq, FAPERJ, INCT and FGV on different grants. We also thank Marcia Waleria Machado, Marcia Marcos, Andrea Virginia, and Rafael Burjack for excellent research assitence.

Abstracts

Using the theoretical framework of Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849., we perform an empirical investigation on how widespread is the predictability of cay-a modified consumption-wealth ratio-once we consider a set of important countries from a global perspective. We chose to work with the set of G7 countries, which represent more than 64% of net global wealth and 46% of global GDP at market exchange rates. We evaluate the forecasting performance of cay using a paneldata approach, since applying cointegration and other time-series techniques is now standard practice in the panel-data literature. Hence, we generalize Lettau and Ludvigson's tests for a panel of important countries. We employ macroeconomic and financial quarterly data for the group of G7 countries, forming an unbalanced panel. For most countries, data is available from the early 1990s until 2014Q1, but for the U.S. economy it is available from 1981Q1 through 2014Q1. Results of an exhaustive empirical investigation are overwhelmingly in favor of the predictive power of cay in forecasting future stock returns and excess returns.

Keywords:
Consumption-Wealth Ratio; Stock Returns; Unbalanced Panel; Cointegrating Residual


Usando o arcabouço teórico de Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849., investigamos a existência de previsibilidade vis-à-vis os excessos de retorno de uma versão modificada da razão consumo-riqueza para os países do grupo G7. Num exercício empírico exaustivo, confirmamos a potencial previsibilidade da razão consumo-riqueza num arcabouço de dados de painel, algo inédito para esse representativo grupo de paises.


1. INTRODUCTION

The link between macroeconomic and financial markets has long driven a great deal of theoretical and empirical work in the macroeconometric literature. Taking the asset-pricing equation as a starting point, and using a present-value approach, one can derive several interesting implications between macroe conomic data and future returns or excess returns. The work of Campbell (1987)Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1987). Cointegration and tests of present value models. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1062-1088., Campbell & Shiller (1987Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1987). Cointegration and tests of present value models. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1062-1088. , 1988a)Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988a). The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. The Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 195-228., Campbell & Deaton (1989)Campbell, J. Y., & Deaton, A. (1989). Why is consumption so smooth? The Review of Economic Studies, 56(3), 357-373., and Campbell & Mankiw (1989)Campbell, J. Y., & Mankiw, N. G. (1989). Consumption, income and interest rates: Reinterpreting the time series evidence. In O. J. Blanchard & S. Fischer (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, Volume 4 (pp. 185-246). MIT Press. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10965
http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10965...
, are good early examples of the connection between macroeconomic and financial variables. Indeed, one should expect some assetreturn predictability following this literature, although the evidence is weak. Compare, for example, the results in Fama & French (1988)Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1988). Dividend yields and expected stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 22(1), 3-25. and Pesaran & Timmermann (1995)Pesaran, M. H., & Timmermann, A. (1995). Predictability of stock returns: Robustness and economic significance. Journal of Finance, 50(4), 1201-1228. with those in Campbell & Thompson (2008)Campbell, J. Y., & Thompson, S. B. (2008). Predicting excess stock returns out of sample: Can anything beat the historical average? The Review of Financial Studies, 21(4), 1509-1531.. Recently, Guillén, Issler, & Saraiva (2015)Guillén, O. T. a. H., Issler, J. V., & Saraiva, D. (2015). Forecasting multivariate time series under present-value model short-and long-run co-movement restrictions. International Journal of Forecasting, 31(3), 862-875. examine the usefulness of imposing different layers of present-value-model restrictions in forecasting financial data - a directly related issue.

In an interesting paper, Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. study the role of transitory trend deviations for consumption, asset holdings and labor income in predicting future stock market fluctuations. Using a forward-looking model, with a novel present-value equation, they show that, when investors expect higher returns in the future, they react by raising current consumption relative to its trend vis-a-vis asset wealth and labor income in order to smooth consumption in line with the asset-pricing equation. Therefore, these current transitory fluctuations of consumption about its trend carry information about the future dynamics of returns and excess returns. These issues are investigated using the time-series framework of cointegration and cross-equation restrictions in the context of a vector autoregressive (VAR) model.

Despite the strong empirical evidence provided by Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. for the U.S. stock market, there has been only a few papers trying to investigate this issue with an a broader international perspective. For example, Ioannidis, Peel, & Matthews (2006)Ioannidis, C., Peel, D., & Matthews, K. (2006). Expected stock returns, aggregate consumption and wealth: Some further empirical evidence. Journal of Macroeconomics, 28(2), 439-445., Tsuji (2009)Tsuji, C. (2009). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns in Japan. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 1(2), 123-133. and Gao & Huang (2008)Gao, P. P., & Huang, K. X. (2008). Aggregate consumption-wealth ratio and the cross-section of stock returns: Some international evidence. Annals of Economics and Finance, 9(1), 1-37. extended the time-series analysis of Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. to other countries, which yields country-specific results. Nitschka (2010)Nitschka, T. (2010). International evidence for return predictability and the implications for long-run covariation of the G7 stock markets. German Economic Review, 11, 527-544., on the other hand, used the consumption-wealth ratio of the U.S. economy as a predictor of foreign stock returns. In a more elaborate paper, Sousa (2010)Sousa, R. M. (2010). Consumption, (dis)aggregate wealth, and asset returns. Journal of Empirical Finance, 17(4), 606-622. shows that housing wealth could be an important component of aggregate wealth when predicting asset returns.

Despite the unquestionable value-added of the subsequent literature, what we see as lacking in it is the use of a broad enough approach to test the idea that transitory trend deviations for consumption (c), asset-wealth holdings (a) and labor income (y) are able to predict future stock market fluctuations, i.e., the usefulness of cay in forecasting returns. If the present-value model holds, it should hold for every country, and not only to the U.S. economy. Instead of employing a country-specific approach to the matter, we propose to use a panel-data approach for a group of relevant countries, which will be able to test the predictability theory in a broader sense. In order to cover a group of relevant countries, we decided to focus on the G7 group: Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States.

The group of G7 countries represents more than 64% of net global wealth (US$263 trillion). They also represent 46% of global GDP evaluated at market exchange rates. Thus, the G7 group is definitely relevant from a global perspective. We limit our study to the group of G7 countries because of the lack of data on asset-wealth holdings for a broader group of countries, especially at the quarterly frequency. Since applying cointegration and other time-series techniques is now standard practice in the panel-data literature, generalizing Lettau and Ludvigson's tests for a panel of countries is immediately feasible, and will be highly informative for global financial markets. Additional advantages of employing panel-data tests vis-a-vis country specific tests is the fact that one gathers more information using the former-the cross-sectional dimension.

The first step of our empirical analysis is to test for the existence of a single cointegrating relationship among consumption, asset wealth, and labor income, with panel cointegration tests. Our performed tests allow for heterogeneity in the linear combination forming the cointegrating relationship (cayh) as well as imposing homogeneity restrictions in it (cay). Here, we also discuss whether or not the estimated linear combinations (cayh) conform to theory in some respects, looking at alternative estimates in the cases where they do not. With our estimates in hand, the next step is to implement an in-sample forecasting exercise, where we investigate whether or not h help to forecast future stock returns and excess returns. We also include in these regressions some financial variables that are widely used in the literature to predict stock returns. Our final forecasting test asks whether or not h help to forecast future stock returns out of sample. Here, the forecasting regression is recursively re-estimated, mimicking closely the exercise a financial analyst will do in practice. Again, we employ a variety of alternative predictors in a horse-race between h) and these potential predictors. Finally, we repeat the in-sample and out-of-sample forecasting tests for cointegrating results that did not conform to theory. and and (or

In performing our empirical tests we employ macroeconomic real quarterly data per capita, measured in 2010 country's own currency, as well as financial data for returns and excess returns. Our main sources of data are the National Accounts Statistics of the OECD database, the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) of the FED of St. Louis, and the International Financial Statistics (IFS), provided by the IMF. We have an unbalanced panel. For most countries, data is available from the early 1990s until 2014Q1, but for the U.S. economy it is available from 1981Q1 through 2014Q1.

Our final results allow for a very broad examination of the present-value theory behind cay, and its potential forecasting power for future returns. First, we find overwhelming evidence of a single cointegration vector for consumption, asset wealth, and labor income. This is true whether or not we allow for heterogeneity in computing the cointegrating relationship. Despite these results, in some cases the coefficients in the linear combination did not conform to theory. The coefficients of asset wealth and labor income must reflect the participation of asset wealth and human capital in total wealth. Thus, they must lie between zero and one and add up to unity. These theoretical restrictions did not hold in some cases, which required alternative estimation techniques. Second, h and h help to forecast future stock returns and excess returns in sample. This is true whether or not we consider additional regressors in forecasting. Third, h help to forecast future stock returns and excess returns in the out-ofsample exercise, usually performing better than alternative regressors. Finally, using estimates of cay and cayh that conform to economic theory does improve forecasts of future accumulated excess returns. and

The next section presents a brief review of the theoretical framework which establishes the presentvalue relationship between cay and expected stock returns. In section 2, we thoroughly detail the ag gregate and financial data that we use to construct our panel. Section 3 presents the results of the integration and cointegration analyses in a penal-data context, i.e., we build the estimates of cay and cayh. Section 4 reports the results of in-sample forecasting. In section 5, we perform out-of-sample forecasts. In section 6, we re-estimate cay and cayh using the fully-modified OLS (FMOLS) estimator to obtain cointegration estimates that conform to theory. Then, we revisit our previous forecasting exercise. Finally, in section 7, we conclude.

2. PRESENT-VALUE THEORY

Consider a representative consumer who invests her/his total wealth and receive a time-varying return. Let Wt and Ct be the aggregate wealth and aggregate consumption in period t, respectively. Rw,t+1 is the net return on aggregate invested wealth. The budget constraint faced by this agent is

(1)

Campbell & Mankiw (1989)Campbell, J. Y., & Deaton, A. (1989). Why is consumption so smooth? The Review of Economic Studies, 56(3), 357-373. suggest log-linearizing (1), obtaining

(2)

where the lower case letters from now on are used to denote the logs of the corresponding variables, rw,t+1≡log(1+R); ρw is the steady-state proportion of investment on wealth; and k1 is a non-interesting constant. For future reference, all ki, i = 2,3,..., are constants as well.

If the consumption-wealth ratio is stationary, it is possible to solve this equation forward in expectations. Thus, taking the conditional expectation and assuming that the transversality condition limi→∞t [ρwi (ct+i−wt+i)] = 0 holds, the log consumption-wealth may be written as

(3)

which means that there is a present value relationship between consumption-wealth ratio and the return on aggregate wealth.

A main problem with (3) is that total wealth has two components: asset wealth and human capital. However, the latter is non observable. Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. deal with this issue in an elegant way. They define aggregate wealth as asset wealth plus human capital Wt = At + Ht, the log of aggregate wealth may be approximated as

(4)

where γ is the average share of asset holdings in total wealth. Furthermore, Campbell (1996)Campbell, J. Y. (1996). Understanding risk and return. Journal of Political Economy, 104(2), 298-345. shows that the return to aggregate wealth, which is given by

(5)

may be log-linearized to get to a tractable intertemporal model with constant coefficients:

(6)

Substituting (4) and (6) into (3), gives

(7)

To deal with non observable that human capital, Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. use the fact that labor income can be interpreted as the dividend on human wealth, implying

(8)

Once more, log-linearizing this expression, we obtain:

where ρh is the steady-state proportion H/(H + Y). Solving it forward, taking the expectation and imposing that limi→∞t [ρih (ht+1 - yt+1)] = 0, the log human capital can be described as

(9)

Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. show that the nonstationary component of human capital is captured by labor income, implying that ht= κ + yt+ µt, where κ is a constant. It is easy to see from (9) that µt = ti=1 ρih (Δyt+i - rh,t+i). This term is a stationary random variable, since we are assuming that Δyt is stationary-labor income has a unit root-and that the return on human wealth is practically constant.

Replacing the log of human wealth in expression (7) by the one obtained in (9), it is possible to rewrite the log consumption-wealth ratio in terms of observable variables:

(10)

(11)

Under the assumption that rw,t, ∆ct and ∆yt are stationary,1 1 We test the evidence of unit root process in consumption and labor income in our panel data. Both don't reject at 5% significance level the null hypothesis of unit root, including individual effects and individual linear trends. equations (10) and (11) imply that ct, at and yt are cointegrated and ct − γat − (1−γ) yt is the cointegrating linear combination labelled as cayt, where (1,− γ,−(1−γ)) is the cointegrating vector (Lettau & Ludvigson, 2004Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. C. (2004). Understanding trend and cycle in asset values: Reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption. American Economic Review, 94(1), 276-299.). Besides, cayt Granger-causes the right-hand term in brackets, since these terms are dated from t + 1 onwards. Therefore, provided that the expected future returns on human capital and consumption growth are relatively smooth, changes in cayt should forecast future changes on asset returns.2 2 Lettau & Ludvigson (2001) find that cayt is a strong predictor of excess returns on aggregate US stock market indexes for both short and long run.

This result is by and large consistent with a wide range of forward-looking models of investor behavior, where agents, disliking sharp fluctuations on consumption, will attempt to smooth out transitory movements in asset wealth due to variations in future expected asset returns. For instance, when higher returns are expected in the future, the forward-looking investors will currently increase their consumption out of their asset wealth and labor income, rising consumption above trend-an increase in cayt-and vice-versa for the case when lower returns are expected in the future.

3. MACROECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DATA

We work with a typical panel of macroeconomic data, where the cross-sectional dimension is small and the time-series dimension is large. As noted above, we possess an unbalanced panel for G7 countries:3 3 The reason for choosing G7 is the lack of data availability for other countries in quarterly frequency, specially of households asset wealth. : Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom and United States. All aggregate variables are quarterly, seasonally adjusted, per capita, and measured in 2010 country's own currency. To deflate data we use the CPI from International Financial Statistics (IFS)-the IMF database-and for quarterly population figures we interpolate annual data provided by OECD.

Consumption data used here is private final consumption expenditure from National Accounts Statistics of OECD's database. Labor income used here is the compensation of employees, provided by the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, but the original source is OECD as well. Asset holdings data were taken separately from each of the G7 country's central bank.

Asset holdings is a critical variable in our analysis, since it determines the time span for each country in the database. Tabela 1 specifies the details of the financial asset holdings data used in this paper.

Table 1
Data sources.

Real asset returns and excess returns are obtained from stock indices. To obtain the log of real gross returns rt for each country, we take their quarterly closing prices, adjusted for dividends. Nominal stock indices are provided by Bloomberg and are deflated using the seasonally adjusted CPI figures from IFS. The stock indices used here are: S&P/TSX composite index for Canada, CAC 40 for France, DAX for Germany, FTSEMIB for Italy, Nikkei 225 for Japan, FTSE 100 for United Kingdom and S&P 500 for United States. To obtain quarterly log of excess returns rt−rf, t, we need to specify the risk-free rate rf,t. The raw data is the percent per annum treasury bill rate from government securities for each country, taken from IFS.

We also considered some additional financial variables such as dividend yield, payout ratio and relative bill rate, in order to extend our analysis and compare the predictive power of cay and that of these variables. Here, we let d − p denote the dividend yield, where d is the log of quarterly dividends per share and p is the log of the stock index. Since Campbell & Shiller (1988b)Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988b). Stock prices, earnings, and expected dividends. Journal of Finance, 43(3), 661-76., this variable has been widely used to forecast excess returns,4 4 Campbell & Shiller (1988b) show that the log dividend-price ratio may be written as dt− pt = t ∑j=1∞ ρja (ra,t+j − Δdt+j), which means that if the dividend-price ratio is high, agents must be expecting either high future asset returns or low dividend growth rates. especially for long horizons. Following Lamont (1998)Lamont, O. (1998). Earnings and expected returns. Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1563-1587., the payout ratio is represented by d − e, where e is the log of quarterly earnings per share. As well as the stock index, both dividends per share and earnings per share are provided by Bloomberg. Finally, we build the relative bill rate RREL subtracting from the T-bill rate its 12-month backward moving average, a method suggested by Hodrick (1992)Hodrick, R. J. (1992). Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for interference and measurement. Review of Financial Studies, 5(3), 357-386..

4. COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS (cay)

First, we test whether each of the variables in cayt ≡ ct−γat(1−γ) yt-consumption (ct), asset wealth (at), and labor income (yt)- have or not a unit root in (log) levels. We perform a panel unit root test proposed by Maddala & Wu (1999)Maddala, G. S., & Wu, S. (1999). A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Special Issue 61, 631-652., which consists of a Fisher (1932)Fisher, R. A. (1932). Statistical methods for research workers (4th ed.). Edinburgh: Oliver and Boyd. test5 5 We choose the Fisher test due to the structure of our data. The asymptotic validity for this test depend on T going to infinity, while for other tests, depend on N going to infinity. that combine the significance levels from individual unit root tests, such as Phillips-Perron (PP) and Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF). For all three variables, in both tests-PP and ADF-the null hypothesis of presence of unit root is not rejected at a ten percent significance level,6 6 Probabilities for Fisher test are computed using asymptotic χ2 distribution. which we interpret to mean that their process is integrated of order one.

Next we conduct two panel cointegration tests to verify if there is a single cointegrating relationship among consumption, asset wealth and labor income. The first one is a residual-based test proposed by (Kao , 1999Kao, C. (1999). Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 90(1), 1-44.), in which homogeneity restrictions are imposed in the cointegrating vector. We strongly reject the null of no cointegration, with a p-value of 0.29%.7 7 Probabilities for Kao test are computed using asymptotic Normal distribution This allows the conclusion of the existence of at least one cointegrating vector. The second test is another Fisher-type test suggested by Maddala & Wu (1999)Maddala, G. S., & Wu, S. (1999). A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Special Issue 61, 631-652. using a Johansen (1991)Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59(6), 1551-1580. procedure to determine the number of cointegrating relations among those three variables in the panel. Since the variables are integrated of order one, we can have zero, one, or two cointegrating vectors. In this case, no homogeneity restrictions are imposed for the cointegrating coefficients. Results are presented in Tabela 2 , and indicate that there is indeed a single cointegrating vector for consumption, asset wealth and labor income. Therefore, we are confident that there is a single cointegrating vector for consumption, asset wealth, and labor income, these three variables sharing two common trends.

Table 2
Johansen Fisher Panel Cointegrating Test.

The next step is to estimate the parameters of the cointegrating vector, cayt ≡ ct−γat (1−γ)y. Instead of imposing a priori theoretical restrictions, where 0 ≤ γ ≤ 1, we estimate the coefficients unrestricted, once imposing homogeneity restrictions-all coefficients are the same across the panel, and once without homogeneity restrictions-coefficients vary across cross-sectional units. In the former we estimate the following cointegrating vector:

(12)

whereas in the latter case, we estimate

(13)

We estimate cointegrating vectors using Johansen (1991)Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59(6), 1551-1580. full-information maximum likelihood (FIML) procedure. Regarding deterministic terms, we assume a linear deterministic trend in data. We chose a vector autoregressive (VAR) model of order two in levels. Tabela 3 presents the estimates of the cointegrating parameters for (12).8 8 With one lag in difference, linear trend and one cointegrating relationship, we estimate the following VEC through a pooled OLS. The right-hand side variable in parenthesis is the error correction term. In long run equilibrium, this term should be zero. However, if any variable of this term deviates from the long run equilibrium, the error correction term would be nonzero and the other variables would adjust to restore the equilibrium relation. The coefficients α measure the speed of adjustment of each endogenous variable towards the equilibrium (Engle & Granger, 1987). One can immediately see that the coefficient of labor income is negative, −0.6406, although it is not significant. Further unit root tests on the cointegrating residual confirm that t does not have a unit root.9 9 Here, and in what follows, we regard this as an informal, but informative test.

Table 3
Panel cointegrating vector estimates.

We now turn to the estimation of equation (13)-cointegrating vector without imposing homogeneity restrictions. We estimate separately a vector error-correction model (VECM) for each country, with results reported in the Appendix A . Again, further unit root tests on the cointegrating residuals confirms that hi,t does not have a unit root.

One thing to note is that in the estimation of (12) and (13) we obtained some counter-intuitive results, or results that go against the present-value theory in section 2. These violations happen when −βa's or −βy's are outside the interval [0,1], which happened for − βy in Tabela 3, and for −βa,i and −βy,i for a few countries in Appendix A. It is hard to explain why these violations happen. There may be measurement error on the data used; it can be the consequence of using a first-order approximation log linear approximation in building (11); etc. In any case, to deal with this issue, we will also consider alterative estimates of (12) and (13) in which these violations are much more infrequent; see the results in section 7.

5. FORECASTING STOCK RETURNS IN-SAMPLE

In this section, we investigate if cay can anticipate real stock returns and real excess returns in sample using a panel-data structure. The intuition here is that variations on cay should precede variations on stock returns, since, theoretically, the forward-looking investor would increase or decrease current con sumption with regard to his wealth, according to future fluctuations on expected stock returns. Figura 1 presents individual graphs for log excess returns-log returns on stock indexes minus the log return on T-bill-and 10 10 Here, we disaggregate the panel into seven time series, one for each country, and detrend them individually in order to eliminate any individual trend effects. normalized series.

Figure 1
Excess Returns and Estimated cay .

For some countries such as Canada, France, Japan and United Kingdom, sharp variations of c clearly preceding spikes in excess returns, for both positive and negative fluctuations. It is also interesting to note that recently most countries have presented a pronounced decreasing in . Another feature of is its counter-cyclical behavior. In fact, when we make a panel regression of consumption growth on contemporaneous controlling for cross section fixed effects, we obtain a coefficient of −0.005181 statistically significant at the 1% level.

Tabela 4 presents in-sample one-quarter-ahead regressions with real returns and excess returns as dependent variables and both h and other financial variables as regressors, including cross-section fixed effects. On all of these regressions, we make White cross-section corrections to the standard errors.11 11 This method considers the pool regression as multivariate regressions with one equation for each cross-section, and computes for the system of equations robust standard errors. The robust variance matrix estimator is given by where NT is the total number of stacked observations and K is the total number of estimated parameters. See Arellano (1987) and Wooldridge (2010). We choose this estimator because of its consistency for panels with large T and fixed N. Regressions with one-period lag of the dependent variable as a regressor are also computed on Tabela 4. It is well known that the LSDV (least squares dummy variable)-the "fixed effects model" we have used in the previous regressions-with a lagged dependent variable generates biased estimates when the time dimension of the panel is small (Judson & Owen, 1999Judson, R. A., & Owen, A. L. (1999). Estimating dynamic panel data models: A guide for macroeconomists. Economics Letters, 65(1), 9-15.). Nevertheless, Nickell (1981)Nickell, S. J. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417-1426. derives an expression for the bias showing that it goes to zero when T approaches infinity. For our purposes, since we are under a large T, small N, environment, the LSDV model bias should be very small, we thus take these in-sample results seriously. Again, we use the White cross-section correction in these regressions as well. and

Table 4
In-sample one-quarter-ahead regressions

In Tabela 4, at one-quarter ahead, both h are not able to predict stock returns, since cay and ctheir coefficients are not statistically significant. The same is true for the other financial variables con sidered in Tabela 4. It is also worth noting that the R2 are extremely low, especially on the regressions with either h a single regressor. and or

From equation (11), one can conclude that cay should be a good predictor of consumption growth as well as of asset returns. Thus, we investigate whether or not it helps to forecast either accumulated consumption growth or accumulated excess returns. Tabela 5 presents the results over horizons span ning 1 to 24 quarters, where regressions are estimated by the LSDV model. Results are presented in Tabela 5.

Table 5
In-sample long-horizon regressions.

From Tabela 5, we conclude the following. First, h. This means that if one wants to make forecasts about consumption growth or excess returns using any of those two variables in a panel, it is better to estimate a single cointegrating vector for the entire panel and build a cay with homogeneous coefficients rather than estimate one cointegrating vector for each country and make an heterogeneous cay. This is a rather convenient result, since 's estimating method is a much more parsimonious way of obtain ing the cointegrating vector for the entire panel. Second, comparing results in Tabela 4 with those in Tabela 5, Tabela 5 show that for short horizons, Tabela 5 shows 's forecasting power as well as its adjusted R2 increasing through time, which is probably due to the strong persistence in cay and excess return series. Third, when we add alternative financial variables on the longer-term regressions, we observe that d − p in regression 5, the same being true for the payout ratio, on regression 6. On the other hand, comparing the R2 of regressions 3 and 7 we observe a better fit for RREL as a predictor up to one year ahead. However, for longer horizons, cay and RREL. For longer horizons, the payout ratio d − e may be considered a good predictor as well. is a much better predictor for both consumption growth and excess returns than has a better performance on predicting excess returns over longer horizons than just one period ahead. In fact, regressions 1 and 3 of is more likely to predict consumption growth, and for longer periods, its forecasting power is greater on excess returns. In fact, regression 3 from is a much better predictor of excess returns than has a better fit. Fourth, in regression 9, we use together with all other financial variables. It is interesting to notice that the forecasting power of dividend yield has vanished. The only two important predictors of excess returns are

From the theoretical framework (equation (11)), cay should Granger-cause asset returns. We perform Granger causality tests12 12 The tests consist of running regressions with different lags, l, of the form and checking the F-statistics for the joint hypothesis of β1 = β2 = ∙∙∙ = βl= 0. investigating if Granger-causes excess stock returns. Indeed, with a lag length from four quarters onwards, we reject the null that does not Granger-cause excess returns, at 1% significance.

6. OUT-OF-SAMPLE FORECASTS

In our view, a true test for predictability should be out-of-sample, since this is the context that is of interest to academics, practitioners, and financial analysts alike. To address this issue, we estimate nested and non-nested models and make out-of-sample forecast comparisons using their mean-squared forecast error (MSFE). Because our results in the previous section using the heterogeneous version of the cointegrating vector (h) were disappointing, from now on we focus only on the homogeneous version, cay. sample until the first quarter of 2004, and then recursively re-estimated adding one quarter at a time and calculating one-step-ahead forecasts until the fourth quarter of 2013. Our forecast accuracy measure is the trace of the MSFE matrix for all countries (implies equal weights across countries).. Nested and non-nested models are first estimated using data from the beginning of the

The so-called Nested Model consists of two regressions. The unrestricted model, which includes and an alternative regressor explaining future excess returns, and the restricted model, where we exclude from the unrestricted model, justifying its name. The so-called Non-Nested Model consists also of two regressions. Model 1, which includes alone, and model 2, which includes only an alternative regressor, so both models are non-nested.

We analyze the MSFE of models using either rt+1 − rf,t+1), and also the two years accumulated excess returns, Σi=18 (rt+i−rf,t+i). Tabela 6 presents the results for nested regressions. From Tabela 6, it is clear that adding reestdt − pt, dt − et, and RRELt. Again, the benefit of adding , with cointegrating parameters estimated using the full sample, or reest , with the cointegrating parameters re-estimated every period. The target variables are the one-step-forward excess returns ( to the benchmark models always decrease the MSFE of the regressions on a two-year horizon. This happens whether the cointegrating coefficients are re-estimated or not. For one quarter ahead, and also do better than the constant and lagged benchmarks, but not when we include in these regressions is greater over the two years accumulated excess returns, which is consistent with the results from long-term regressions above.

Table 6
Out-of-sample nested comparisons.

In Tabela 7, we extend our analysis by making nonnested forecasts. Compared to the financial variables, d − e. However, when making forecasts over one quarter ahead, both reest produces superior forecasts regardless of whether its coefficients are re-estimated or whether we want to predict the next quarter or two years accumulated excess returns. The strength of as a predictor may be noticed specially with regard to the payout ratio, and over the MSFE ratio is greater for two years accumulated excess returns. At this time length, the forecasting power of even overcomes the predictive power of lagged excess returns. Moreover, comparing the first four rows with the last four, we see that has a superior forecasting power than its re-estimated version, as one would expect.

Table 7
Out-of-sample nonnested comparisons.

All in all, we find that equation (11). beats most alternatives across both horizons investigated here. Outof-sample results are consistent with the in-sample results as a whole, confirming the predictability of embedded in

7. COINTEGRATION AND FORECASTING WITH A FMOLS ESTIMATE OF cay

As pointed out in the Introduction, from a theoretical perspective, the cointegrating vector should be

where 0 ≤ γ ≤ 1 should be the share of asset wealth in total wealth. However, inspection of our empirical results in section 4 and the Appendices, shows that not always these theoretical restrictions were obeyed. Two possible reasons for that are measurement error on the components of cayt or the fact that we obtain the present-value equation (11) using a first-order log-linear approximation.

Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. and some subsequent papers in the literature also present these prob lems, especially the fact that coefficients did not add up to unity, which was not viewed as major issue. So, we follow the early literature and try to estimate the cointegrating vector using a method that could in principle yield estimates of the homogeneous cointegrating vector (1,−βa,−βy), where 0 ≤ βay ≤ 1, with an analogous restriction binding also for the heterogeneous case. However, we do not impose that βa+ βy = 1. To implement that, we apply the Fully Modified Ordinary Least Squares (FMOLS) proposed by Phillips & Hansen (1990)Phillips, P. C. B., & Hansen, B. E. (1990). Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with I (1) processes. Review of Economic Studies, 57(1), 99-125.. This approach, in contrast to the standard OLS, eliminates problems of asymptotic bias of the estimates caused by the long run correlation between the cointegrating equation and stochastic regressors innovations. This allows inference on the cointegrating vector.

Tabela 8 reports the results on the homogeneous cointegrating vector, obtained from the FMOLS for the entire panel. In Appendix B, we present the heterogeneous vectors results, derived from the time-series FMOLS regressions estimated separately for each country.

Table 8
Panel homogeneous cointegrating vector.

For the homogeneous cointegrating vector, contrary to previous results, we now do not observe a negative share for human-capital wealth. Also, for the heterogeneous case, we only observed two instances with negative shares for asset wealth (France and the UK), which are very small numerically and statistically insignificant. Thus, from a practical and statistical point-of-view, our FMOLS cointegrating vectors are theoretically valid.

With these new results in hand, we build f, the homogeneous version of the cointegrating residual using FMOLS, and fh its heterogenous counterpart. Once again, we check the stationarity of f and fh by performing the Fisher-ADF and PP panel unit root tests, including individual intercepts but not any trends. For both variables, the presence of unit root is strongly rejected on both ADF and PP tests, confirming their stationarity.

Figura 2 shows variations of f. For instance, considering the year of 2013, the excess returns of France, Italy, Japan and United Kingdom have already followed the latest f swings. On the other hand, United States and Canada still show opposite movements between those two variables. Thus, if f is indeed a good predictor of excess returns, we should expect a decline in excess return's path in the next few quarters of 2014 and 2015 for both Canada and United States. preceding some movements on excess returns for countries such as Canada, France, Germany and United Kingdom. In addition, we notice that some countries present a faster responsiveness of excess returns over movements on

Figure 2
Excess Returns and Estimated cay .

Next, we perform the in-sample one-quarter-ahead predictability tests using f or hf. Results are presented in Tabela 9. Contrary to previous results, now, both f and fh can significantly forecast one-quarter-ahead stock returns and excess returns. But, other financial variables included in the regressions cannot.

Table 9
In-sample one-quarter-ahead regressions.

Tabela 10 we presents the results of forecasting tests for in-sample long-term regressions, investigating the impact of f and fh over accumulated consumption growth and accumulated excess returns.

Table 10
In-sample long-horizon regressions.

From Panel A on Tabela 10 we notice that fh is a better predictor of consumption growth than f, based on a larger adjusted R2. In contrast, in Panel B, f is a better predictor overall. Comparing f with the other financial variables (rows 4 and 5) f is a much better predictor of excess returns than d − p, except for a horizon of six years. The same is not true for the payout ratio, on row 6. On the other hand, comparing the R2 of rows 3 and 7 we observe a better fit with RREL as a predictor only up to three quarters ahead. On row 9, we make the long-horizon regressions on f and all financial cayf variables together, results are still the same as in Tabela 5- f and RREL as stronger predictors of excess returns for intermediate horizons, and for longer horizons the payout ratio d − e may also be considered a good predictor.

Tabela 11 presents the results of the out-of-sample forecasting exercise for excess returns. Again, we make both nested and nonnested comparisons and use either f or reestf, which has its coefficients recursively re-estimated using FMOLS.

Table 11
Out-of-sample nested comparisons.

At the one-quarter-ahead horizon, results for reestf in Tabela 11 are disappointing, but f still beats lagged excess returns and the constant-return model. For the accumulated excess returns up to two years ahead, both f or reestf forecast much better than any of the alternatives. The decrease in MSFE can reach up to 14%, which is impressive compared to previous results.

Tabela 12 present the results of the non-nested tests. For accumulated excess returns, note that f or reestf produce superior forecasts than any other alternative predictor. For one-step-ahead, the same can be said about f, with an excellent out-of-sample performance beating alternative predictors by more than 15%. However, reestf is beaten almost by all alternative predictors, with the exception of d −e.

Table 12
Out-of-sample nonnested comparisons.

The results in the current section show that taking into account theoretical restrictions may im prove forecasting performance - compare the results in Tables 6 and 11, and results in Tables 7 and 12 -especially those of accumulated excess returns over the two-year horizon. These empirical results are in line with those obtained by Guillén et al. (2015Guillén, O. T. a. H., Issler, J. V., & Saraiva, D. (2015). Forecasting multivariate time series under present-value model short-and long-run co-movement restrictions. International Journal of Forecasting, 31(3), 862-875.), who compared the out-of-sample forecasting per formance of present-value models for the long-and short-interest rates, and for prices and dividends, with those of an unrestricted VAR, a cointegrating VAR, and a VAR with imposed cointegration and common-cycle restrictions, for these same variables. There, it became clear the advantages of imposing a fully-fledged theoretical model, although an intermediately restricted model produced forecasting winners more frequently.

8. CONCLUSIONS

Using the theoretical framework of Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849., we perform an empirical investigation on how widespread is the predictability of cay-a modified consumption-wealth ratio-once we consider a set of important countries from a global perspective. We chose to work with the set of G7 countries, which represent more than 64% of net global wealth (US$263 trillion), and 46% of global GDP at market exchange rates. We evaluate the forecasting performance of cay using a panel-data approach, since applying cointegration and other time-series techniques is now standard practice in the panel-data literature. Hence, generalizing Lettau and Ludvigson's tests for a panel of countries is feasible and highly informative for global financial markets.

We employ macroeconomic and financial quarterly data for the group of G7 countries, forming an unbalanced panel. For most countries, data is available from the early 1990s until 2014Q1, but for the U.S. economy it is available from 1981Q1 through 2014Q1. Our final results allowed a very broad examination of the present-value theory behind cay, which conclusions we list below:

  1. We find overwhelming evidence of a single cointegration vector for consumption, asset wealth, and labor income, in forming cay.

  2. In some cases, the coefficients in the cointegrating linear combination did not conform to theory, since they must lie between zero and one and add up to unity. This issue required alternative estimation techniques and forecast evaluation.

  3. Estimates of cay help to forecast future stock returns and excess returns in sample. This is true whether or not we consider additional regressors in forecasting.

  4. Estimates of cay help to forecast future stock returns and excess returns in the out-of-sample exercise, usually performing better than alternative regressors.

  5. Finally, using estimates of cay that conform to economic theory does improve forecasts of future accumulated excess returns up to the two-year horizon.

All in all, we believe that our evidence has shown that the predictive power of cay is not a phenomenon restricted to the U.S. economy, but a much wider phenomenon, which deserves to be studied more broadly.

  • *
    We are especially grateful for the comments and suggestions given by Wagner Gaglianone, Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira, Ricardo Sousa and other seminar participants at the 2nd International Workshop on "Financial Markets and Nonlinear Dynamics" (FMND) in Paris. Any remaining errors are ours. Both Castro and Issler gratefully acknowledge the support from CNPq, FAPERJ, INCT and FGV on different grants. We also thank Marcia Waleria Machado, Marcia Marcos, Andrea Virginia, and Rafael Burjack for excellent research assitence.
  • 1
    We test the evidence of unit root process in consumption and labor income in our panel data. Both don't reject at 5% significance level the null hypothesis of unit root, including individual effects and individual linear trends.
  • 2
    Lettau & Ludvigson (2001)Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849. find that cayt is a strong predictor of excess returns on aggregate US stock market indexes for both short and long run.
  • 3
    The reason for choosing G7 is the lack of data availability for other countries in quarterly frequency, specially of households asset wealth.
  • 4
    Campbell & Shiller (1988b)Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988b). Stock prices, earnings, and expected dividends. Journal of Finance, 43(3), 661-76. show that the log dividend-price ratio may be written as dt− pt = tj=1 ρja (ra,t+j − Δdt+j), which means that if the dividend-price ratio is high, agents must be expecting either high future asset returns or low dividend growth rates.
  • 5
    We choose the Fisher test due to the structure of our data. The asymptotic validity for this test depend on T going to infinity, while for other tests, depend on N going to infinity.
  • 6
    Probabilities for Fisher test are computed using asymptotic χ2 distribution.
  • 7
    Probabilities for Kao test are computed using asymptotic Normal distribution
  • 8
    With one lag in difference, linear trend and one cointegrating relationship, we estimate the following VEC through a pooled OLS.
    The right-hand side variable in parenthesis is the error correction term. In long run equilibrium, this term should be zero. However, if any variable of this term deviates from the long run equilibrium, the error correction term would be nonzero and the other variables would adjust to restore the equilibrium relation. The coefficients α measure the speed of adjustment of each endogenous variable towards the equilibrium (Engle & Granger, 1987Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276.).
  • 9
    Here, and in what follows, we regard this as an informal, but informative test.
  • 10
    Here, we disaggregate the panel into seven time series, one for each country, and detrend them individually in order to eliminate any individual trend effects.
  • 11
    This method considers the pool regression as multivariate regressions with one equation for each cross-section, and computes for the system of equations robust standard errors. The robust variance matrix estimator is given by
    where NT is the total number of stacked observations and K is the total number of estimated parameters. See Arellano (1987)Arellano, M. (1987). Computing robust standard errors for within-groups estimators. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 49(4), 431-434. and Wooldridge (2010)Wooldridge, J. M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data (2nd ed.). The MIT Press.. We choose this estimator because of its consistency for panels with large T and fixed N.
  • 12
    The tests consist of running regressions with different lags, l, of the form
    and checking the F-statistics for the joint hypothesis of β1 = β2 = ∙∙∙ = βl= 0.

APPENDIX A. VECM HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATING VECTORS

This appendix provides the results from the VEC regressions for each country separately. Tabela A-1 shows the cointegrating vector parameters estimates when we relax the homogeneity restrictions, leading to heterogeneous coefficients among countries. On every VEC specification, we include an intercept in the cointegrating equation, we use one lag in difference for the endogenous variables and impose on cointegrating relationship among them.

With these estimated parameters we construct the variable h, which represents the cointe grating residual when we allow for heterogeneity on coefficients, just as we describe in section 4.

Table A-1
Heterogeneous cointegrating vectors.

APPENDIX B. FMOLS HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATING VECTORS

This appendix provides the results from the FMOLS regressions for each country separately. Tabela B 2 shows the cointegrating vector parameters estimates when we relax the homogeneity restrictions, leading to heterogeneous coefficients among countries. In addition, in the specification, we include distinct constants in the cointegrating structure for each country.

With these estimated parameters we construct the variable fh, which represents the cointe grating residual when we allow for heterogeneity on coefficients, just as we describe in section 7.

Table B-2
Heterogeneous cointegrating vectors.

REFERENCES

  • Arellano, M. (1987). Computing robust standard errors for within-groups estimators. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 49(4), 431-434.
  • Campbell, J. Y. (1987). Does saving anticipate declining labor income? An alternative test of the permanent income hypothesis. Econometrica, 55(6), 1249-1273.
  • Campbell, J. Y. (1996). Understanding risk and return. Journal of Political Economy, 104(2), 298-345.
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Deaton, A. (1989). Why is consumption so smooth? The Review of Economic Studies, 56(3), 357-373.
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Mankiw, N. G. (1989). Consumption, income and interest rates: Reinterpreting the time series evidence. In O. J. Blanchard & S. Fischer (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, Volume 4 (pp. 185-246). MIT Press. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10965
    » http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10965
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1987). Cointegration and tests of present value models. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1062-1088.
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988a). The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. The Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 195-228.
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988b). Stock prices, earnings, and expected dividends. Journal of Finance, 43(3), 661-76.
  • Campbell, J. Y., & Thompson, S. B. (2008). Predicting excess stock returns out of sample: Can anything beat the historical average? The Review of Financial Studies, 21(4), 1509-1531.
  • Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276.
  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1988). Dividend yields and expected stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 22(1), 3-25.
  • Fisher, R. A. (1932). Statistical methods for research workers (4th ed.). Edinburgh: Oliver and Boyd.
  • Gao, P. P., & Huang, K. X. (2008). Aggregate consumption-wealth ratio and the cross-section of stock returns: Some international evidence. Annals of Economics and Finance, 9(1), 1-37.
  • Guillén, O. T. a. H., Issler, J. V., & Saraiva, D. (2015). Forecasting multivariate time series under present-value model short-and long-run co-movement restrictions. International Journal of Forecasting, 31(3), 862-875.
  • Hodrick, R. J. (1992). Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for interference and measurement. Review of Financial Studies, 5(3), 357-386.
  • Ioannidis, C., Peel, D., & Matthews, K. (2006). Expected stock returns, aggregate consumption and wealth: Some further empirical evidence. Journal of Macroeconomics, 28(2), 439-445.
  • Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59(6), 1551-1580.
  • Judson, R. A., & Owen, A. L. (1999). Estimating dynamic panel data models: A guide for macroeconomists. Economics Letters, 65(1), 9-15.
  • Kao, C. (1999). Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 90(1), 1-44.
  • Lamont, O. (1998). Earnings and expected returns. Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1563-1587.
  • Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 815-849.
  • Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. C. (2004). Understanding trend and cycle in asset values: Reevaluating the wealth effect on consumption. American Economic Review, 94(1), 276-299.
  • Maddala, G. S., & Wu, S. (1999). A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Special Issue 61, 631-652.
  • Nickell, S. J. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417-1426.
  • Nitschka, T. (2010). International evidence for return predictability and the implications for long-run covariation of the G7 stock markets. German Economic Review, 11, 527-544.
  • Pesaran, M. H., & Timmermann, A. (1995). Predictability of stock returns: Robustness and economic significance. Journal of Finance, 50(4), 1201-1228.
  • Phillips, P. C. B., & Hansen, B. E. (1990). Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with I (1) processes. Review of Economic Studies, 57(1), 99-125.
  • Sousa, R. M. (2010). Consumption, (dis)aggregate wealth, and asset returns. Journal of Empirical Finance, 17(4), 606-622.
  • Tsuji, C. (2009). Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns in Japan. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 1(2), 123-133.
  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data (2nd ed.). The MIT Press.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Oct-Dec 2016
Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rbe@fgv.br