Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Using a Bayesian approach to estimate and compare new Keynesian DSGE models for the Brazilian economy: the role for endogenous persistence

Abstracts

New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models have been developed for monetary policy analysis in open economies. For this purpose, the basic model must be enriched with the sources of nominal and real rigidities which are capable of explaining the observed output and inflation persistence. Under this perspective, we use the Bayesian approach to estimate and compare alternative model specifications for the Brazilian economy with respect to two endogenous persistence mechanisms widely supported by the international empirical literature: habit formation and price indexation. Using data for the inflation target period, we conclude for the relevance of both mechanisms, although the evidence is unexpectly less robust for price indexation. Furthermore, impulse-response functions are built to describe the dynamic effects of domestic and foreign real and monetary shocks.

New Keynesian models; price indexation; habit formation; Bayesian econometrics


Modelos de equilíbrio geral dinâmicos e estocásticos têm sido desenvolvidos para a análise de política monetária em economias abertas. Com este propósito, o modelo básico precisa ser enriquecido com as fontes de rigidez nominal e real que são capazes de explicar a persistência observada no produto e na inflação. Com esta perspectiva, a metodologia bayesiana é usada para estimar e comparar alternativas especificações de modelos para a economia brasileira no tocante a dois mecanismos endógenos de persistência amplamente postulados pela literatura empírica internacional: formação de hábito e indexação de preços. Usando dados do período de metas de inflação, nossa conclusão é pela relevância de ambos os mecanismos, embora a evidência seja inesperadamente menos robusta para indexação de preços. Além disso, funções impulsoresposta são construídas para descrever os efeitos dinâmicos de choques estruturais domésticos e externos, reais e monetários.


Using a Bayesian approach to estimate and compare new Keynesian DSGE models for the Brazilian economy: the role for endogenous persistence* * I am grateful to Ajax Moreira (IPEA), Marco Bonomo (FGV-RJ), Maria Cristina Terra (FGV- RJ) and René Garcia (Universidade de Montreal) for useful comments.

Marcos Antonio C. da Silveira

Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada (lPEA). Address: Avenida Presidente Antonio Carlos, 51, sala 1714, Rio de Janeiro, 20020-010. E-mail: mailto:silveira@ipea.gov.br

ABSTRACT

New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models have been developed for monetary policy analysis in open economies. For this purpose, the basic model must be enriched with the sources of nominal and real rigidities which are capable of explaining the observed output and inflation persistence. Under this perspective, we use the Bayesian approach to estimate and compare alternative model specifications for the Brazilian economy with respect to two endogenous persistence mechanisms widely supported by the international empirical literature: habit formation and price indexation. Using data for the inflation target period, we conclude for the relevance of both mechanisms, although the evidence is unexpectly less robust for price indexation. Furthermore, impulse-response functions are built to describe the dynamic effects of domestic and foreign real and monetary shocks.

Keywords: New Keynesian models; price indexation; habit formation; Bayesian econometrics.

JEL Code: E32, E52, F41.

RESUMO

Modelos de equilíbrio geral dinâmicos e estocásticos têm sido desenvolvidos para a análise de política monetária em economias abertas. Com este propósito, o modelo básico precisa ser enriquecido com as fontes de rigidez nominal e real que são capazes de explicar a persistência observada no produto e na inflação. Com esta perspectiva, a metodologia bayesiana é usada para estimar e comparar alternativas especificações de modelos para a economia brasileira no tocante a dois mecanismos endógenos de persistência amplamente postulados pela literatura empírica internacional: formação de hábito e indexação de preços. Usando dados do período de metas de inflação, nossa conclusão é pela relevância de ambos os mecanismos, embora a evidência seja inesperadamente menos robusta para indexação de preços. Além disso, funções impulsoresposta são construídas para descrever os efeitos dinâmicos de choques estruturais domésticos e externos, reais e monetários.

1. INTRODUCTION

New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models with imperfect competition and nominal stickiness have been developed for monetary policy analysis in open economies. Built from first principles, these models give rise to a macroeconomic dynamics lead by fundamental shocks, at the same time that they preserve the analytical tractability of the traditional Mundell-Fleming approach. In using these models to recommend how central banks should react to the business cycles, it is necessary to determine the sources - as well as evaluate the degree - of the nominal and real rigidities present in the economy. Under this perspective, (Christiano et al., 2005) and (Smets and Woulters, 2004) have argued that endogenous persistence mechanisms, such as habit formation and price indexation, must be added to the basic new Keynesian model in order to reproduce the observed output and inflation persistence. Many empirical studies have addressed empirically this question for small open economies, such as (Justiniano and Preston, 2004) for Australia, Canada and New Zealand, (Caputo et al., 2005) for Chile and (Liu, 2005) for New Zealand. In general, they conclude for the relevance of habit formation, although the evidence is less robust for price indexation. Following this line of research, this paper estimate and compare alternative model specifications for the Brazilian economy with respect to the existence of these persistence sources. The paper also analizes the dynamics properties of the economy under the best specification through impulse-response functions.

As a workhorse, we build a two-country version of the model by (Gali and Monacelli, 2005), which extends for a small open economy the new Keynesian DSGE with Calvo-type staggered price-setting developed initially for closed economies. A distinctive feature of the model is that the terms of trade enters directly into the new Keynesian Phillips curve as a second pushing-cost variable in addition to the output gap, creating in this way a new source of inflationary pressure. Most part of the literature built small-open economy models by assuming that foreign variables follow exogenous processes. This paper takes an alternative route and derive the small open economy directly as a limit-case of the two-country model. The advantage of this procedure is that we derive rigorously the small economy as part of a integrated world economy, preserving all international linkages and without taking the risk of setting aside relevant international channels of monetary transmission.

In the empirical part of the paper, the Bayesian approach is used to estimate alternative model specifications with respect to the presence of different endogenous persistence mechanisms, in which Brazilian data is used for the small economy and U.S. data for the rest of the world. The parameters of both economies are estimated simultaneously. The Bayesian approach has become widespread in the empirical literature as it allows us

to use our previous beliefs on structural parameters in making inference about them. For the Brazilian case, this Bayesian property is expected to be particularly helpful, since we could compensate the shortness of Brazilian historical series with the information provided by the estimation of analogous models with data from other countries. Furthermore, in using posterior odds, Bayesian approach makes easier a formal model comparisons, so that we can evaluate the relative importance of each type of endogenous persistence to explain the data.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out the model. Section 3 carries out the empirical analysis. Section 4 concludes.

2. MODEL

The world is inhabited by a continuum of infinite-lived households, indexed by j ∈ [0, 1]. Each household lives in one of two countries: households on the interval [0, n) live in the Home country, while households on the interval [n, 1] live in the Foreign country. The parameter n measures the relative size of the Home country. The small Home country case can be derived by taking the limit of the two-country model as n → 0. Households maximize a lifetime utility subject to a interteporal budget constraint. Real rigidity stemming from consumption inertia is introduced through habit formation. The international financial market is complete, allowing for international risk sharing. Central banks in both countries follow a Taylor-type rule in setting the nominal short term interest rate, which embodies interest rate smoothness and monetary policy shocks.

Each household owns a competitive-monopolistic firm producing a differentiated good. Thus, there is also a continuum of firms indexed by i ∈ [0, 1], such that firms on the interval [0, n) are located in the Home country, while firms on the interval [n, 1] are located in the Foreign country. Calvo-style price-setting is assumed, but firms not adjusting prices optimally have their prices indexed fo past inflation. Firms use only labor for production through a CRS technology subject to productivity shocks. There is no investment. Households' labor supply reacts elastically to real wage. Labor market is competitive and internationally segmented.

All Home and Foreign goods are tradable and the law of one price (LOP) holds for all of them. Therefore, the model sets aside the effects of nontradability and international market segmentation on the real exchange rate fluctuation. In this sense, the only reason for PPP (purchase power parity) violation is the introduction of a home bias in households' preferences. In addition, prices are set in the producer's currency.

We derive the general equilibrium dynamics for the log-linearized model around the steady state, in which all driving forces of the economy remain constant in their long-run equilibrium levels. Without loss of generality, we log-linearize the particular case of the model with symmetric preferences and identical wealth conditions. This procedure is common in the literature as it makes the log-linearization much easier.

Throughout the paper, we describe only the Home economy's structure, while its Foreign counterpart is presented only if necessary. Starred variables, as well as expressions into brackets [ ], refer to the Foreign country. Lowercase variables are in log deviation from steady state, so that constants are eliminated.

2.1. Households

2.1.1. Preferences

The typical Home jth household maximizes the lifetime utility function1 1 New Keynesian models assume that nominal short-term interest rate is the monetary policy instrument, so that money supply is endogenous. Thus, we follow the literature and do not put money demand into preferences explicitly.

where β is the intertemporal discount factor, φ is the inverse of the wage-elasticity of labor supply and σ is the inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption . In order to reproduce observed output persistence, we introduce external habit formation - with degree of intensity indexed by h - through the term Ht, where Ct-1 is the aggregate past consumption index, which will be derived below. As usual, we assume that 0 < β < 1, φ > 1, σ > 0 and 0 < h < 1.

The variable is defined as the CES composite consumption index

where µ is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution between a bundle of Home goods and a bundle of Foreign goods , while α determines the share of the imported (Foreign) goods on the Home household j's consumption expenditure and, as we will see below, is inversely related to the degree of home bias. We assume that 0 < α < 1 and µ > 0.

The variables and are defined respectively by the CES composite consumption indexes

where (i) and (i) are respectively the Home jth household's consumption levels of Home ith good, with i ∈[0, n), and Foreign ith good, with i ∈ [n, 1]. The parameter ε is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution among goods produced in the same country. We assume that ε > 0.

The Foreign households' preferences are the same, except for eq.(2), which assumes the form

where α* is the share of the imported (Home) goods on the Foreign jth household consumption expenditure.

2.1.2. Intratemporal Consumption Choice

For clearness of exposition, we explain how the typical household allocates wealth among goods intratemporally before describing her intertemporal budget constraint and derive her intertemporal consumption choice. The Home jth household takes as given the Home-currency market price of all Home and Foreign goods, denoted respectively by PH,t(i), with i ∈ [0, n), and PF,t(i), with i ∈ [n, 1]. Thus, for any fixed levels of and , the optimal (i) and (i) are given respectively by2 2 We minimize and subject to eqs.(3).

where PH,t and PF,t are the Home-currency price indexes of the domestically produced goods and imported goods from the Foreign country, given respectively by

How and are determined? Given PH,t and PF,t derived in the problem above and derived in the intertemporal consumer problem below, the optimal consumption allocation between Home and Foreign goods is given by

where Pt is the Home consumer price index (CPI), given by

Proceeding analogously with the Foreign country, we have that the Foreign CPI index is given by

2.2. Home bias

It is important to understand how the parameter a is related to the degree of home bias in Home households' preferences. For that, suppose without loss of generality that PH,t = PF,t. In this case, it follows from eqs.(6) and (7) that α is exactly equal to the share of imported goods in Home consumption expenditure. Having in mind this result, it is intuitive that α should fall with the relative size of the Home country, given by parameter n defined above, and with the degree of home bias in Home households' preferences. A tractable way to formalize these ideas is to define

where the parameter is given exogenously in the model and its inverse, , is an index for the degree of home bias in Home households' preferences.3 3 Note that a change in n alters α even if the degree of home bias remains constant. For instance, if the reason for home bias is international trade barries, can be interpreted as an index of openness for the Home country. Applying the same procedure to the Foreign country, we set α* ≡ *n.4 4 In log-linearizing the particular model specification with symmetric preferences, we must set = *. In the particular case with fully opened countries, when = * = 1, we get α = 1 - n and α* = n. There is no home bias in this case, since the weight of imported goods in the aggregate consumption of each country is naturally given by the relative size of the Home and Foreign countries. On the other hand, in the particular case with fully closed countries, when = * = 0, we get α = α* = 0 even if both countries are large (n = 0.5 for instance).

2.3. World aggregate demand

The LOP holds for all goods, so that PH,t(i) = (i) for i ∈ [0, n) and PF,t(i) = (i) for i ∈ [n, 1], where εt is the nominal exchange rate (Home-currency price of one unit of the Foreign currency). Substituting these results into eqs.(5) and their Foreign counterparts, we get PH,t = and PF,t = . Using these results, we can substitute eq.(4) for (i) and its Foreign counterpart for (i) into the definition below for the Home ith good's world aggregate demand, denoted by (i), so that we get

where

and the aggregate counterparts for Home and Foreign consumption indexes are given by

2.3.1. Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Given the CPI index Pt derived above, the period budget constraint of the Home jth household is given by , where is the one-period stochastic discount factor, Wt is the Home nominal wage and is the nominal cum-dividends value of the portfolio held by the household j at t-1.

The optimal consumption allocation between periods t and t+1 meets the marginal condition , where Rt is the one-period nominal spot interest rate. Log-linearizing this equation and using eqs.(12), the log Home aggregate consumption ct meets the Euler equation

where πtpt - pt–1 is the Home consumer price index (CPI) inflation. The elasticity of current consumption with respect to expected real interest rate falls with h, since habit formation implies that household smooths not only the consumption level but also the change in consumption.

2.3.2. Labor Supply

The marginal condition for Home jth household with respect to labor supply is given by , where j ∈ [0, n). Using this condition to substitute for into the definition below for the Home aggregate labor supply, denoted by , and using eq.(12), we have that

2.3.3. Inflation, Terms of Trade (TOT) and Real Exchange Rate

Now, we derive the relationship between inflation, terms of trade and real exchange rate. The Home terms of trade (TOT), defined as St, is the Home country's relative price of the imported (Foreign) goods in terms of the domestic (Home) goods. It follows from the LOP that the Foreign TOT is given by . Therefore, an improvement (deterioration) of the Home TOT - i.e. a lower (higher) St - reduces (increases) the Home goods' world competitiveness. Dividing the Home CPI index in eq.(7) by PH,t and PF,t [and its Foreign counterpart in eq.(8) by and , we get

where g' (St) > 0, h' (St) < 0, g*' (St) > 0 and h*' (St) < 0. Log-linearizing eqs.(15) and (18), we get

where the Home and Foreign log domestic inflation rates (i.e., the percent change of the price index of the goods produced domestically) are given by πH,tpH,t – pH,t–1 and . Equation (19) tells us that the size of the positive effect of a deterioration in Home TOT on the gap between the Home CPI and domestic inflation rates increases with the weight of the imported (Foreign) goods in the Home households' preferences, given by α = (1 - n), which in turn falls with the relative size of the Home country n and with the degree of home bias , inversely related to .5 5 This result is very intuitive when we note that the degree of home bias is inversely related to the degree of trade openness. An analogous argument is true for the Foreign country's counterpart in eq.(20). Two particular cases are of interest: (1) for closed countries, when = 0, we get πt = πH,t and ; (2) for a small Home country, when n is very close to 0, we get .

Combining the LOP with eqs.(15) and (17), we get Qt, where Qt is the Home country's real exchange rate. Although the LOP holds for all goods individually, Qt is an increasing function of St. Intuitively, home bias implies that Pt and are consumer-based price indexes with different weights on the Home and Foreign goods. Log-linearizing this result, we get

This equation highlights that home bias is the only source of PPP violation, since qt = 0 every period when there is no home bias ( = 1).

2.3.4. International Risk Sharing

We assume complete international financial markets. Hence, following (Chari et al., 2002), we can combine the Home and Foreign marginal conditions with respect to Arrow -Debrew securities positions - relative to a same history between two periods - in order to get the international risk sharing (IRS) condition

where . It follows from this result that home bias allows for a variable gap between Home and Foreign (per-capita) households' consumption growth rates, even if financial markets are complete. The intuition is that, with home bias, changes in Home TOT produce real exchange rate fluctuation, which in turn gives rise to a variable gap between the Home and Foreign's intertemporal relative price of consumption. Following a general procedure in the literature, which is without loss of generality, we assume the same initial conditions - in terms of relative net asset positions - for Home and Foreign households, so that = 1. Using eqs.(12) to substitute for and into eq.(22), we get an aggregate version of the IRS condition, which can be log-linearized to yield

2.3.5. Uncovered Interest Parity

As inferred from subsection (2.1.3), the Home-currency equilibrium prices of the one-period zero-cupon bonds denominated in Home and Foreign currencies are given respectively by = Et[Dt,t+1] and = Et[ Dt,t+1εt+1], where Dt,t+1 is the one-period Home SDF. Combining these equations, we get the uncovered interest parity (UIP) Et = 0. Log-linearizing this equation and using the results (15) and (17), we get

where rt – EtH,t+1] and . As should be clear, the UIP condition (24) is not an additional independent equilibrium condition.

2.4. Firms

Each Home and Foreign household owns a competitive-monopolistic firm producing a differentiated good. Therefore, there is also a continuum of firms indexed by i ∈ [0, 1], such that firms on the interval [0, n) are located in the Home country, while firms on the interval [n, 1] are located in the Foreign country. Whenever allowed, each firm sets its price in order to maximize profits subject to an isoelastic demand curve, which is given by eq.(10) for the Home firms. Firms use only a homogeneous type of labor for production. Labor market is competitive and internationally segmented. There is no investment.

2.4.1. Technology and Cost Minimization

All Home firms operate the same CRS technology

where Yt(i) is the Home ith firm's output, Lt (i) is the Home ith firm's labor demand and At is the Home total factor productivity shifter, which follows the AR(1) process

where 0 < ρ < 1 and ξA,t are i.i.d Gaussian shocks. All Foreign firms operate a similar technology, except for the fact that ρρ* is possible. This technology implies that the Home nominal marginal cost is given by . Defining the Home real marginal cost - in terms of domestic goods - as MCt, we can use definition (15) to get

so that MCt depends positively on the real wage and the TOT, since g (St) > 0 in eq.(15).

2.4.2. Labor Demand

Substituting eq.(25) into the definition below for Home aggregate labor demand, we get

where Yt is the Home aggregate output index, defined as

and Ut is a variable that measures the dispersion of the Home firms' outputs.

2.4.3. Price-Setting

Calvo-style price-setting is assumed. In addition, we introduce inflation persistence by allowing for price indexation to past inflation. Every period, a fraction 1 - ø(0 < ø < 1) of randomly selected firms set prices optimally. In this case, each Home firm i sets a new price (i) in order to maximize the present value of its stream of expected future profits, which is given by Vt(i) = Et[Dt,t+sDVt+s (i)], where Dt,t+s = is the s-period Home SDF at period t, DVt+s(i) = (i) is the profit at period t+s and (i) is the world demand for Home ith good at period t+s, which is given by eq.(10).6 6 We assume that firms not adjusting prices optimally also meet demand, so that Yt +s( i) = ( i) for any s. Log-linearizing the solution of this problem, we get7 7 We suppress the index i because all firms adjusting prices optimally take the same decision, since they face identical current and expected future marginal costs.

where ψ ≡ ln. The firm sets the new price as a (gross) markup - with size in log equal to ψ - over the weighted average of the current and expected future nominal marginal costs. This forward-looking behavior arises because the firm recognizes that the new price price will be effective for a random number of periods. As the firm faces an isoelastic demand curve, it does not adjust price in response to a shift in this curve if current or expected future marginal costs remain unaltered. This result implies that inflationary pressures must have a cost-pushing origin, which is a central property of the new Keynesian models. We can derive a similar equation for the Foreign country, where ø* ≠ ø is allowed. In particular, we have ø = ø* = 0 under flexible prices, so that every Home firm adjusts optimally its price every period according to the pricing rule

On the other hand, each firm i of the other fraction ø, which does not choose price optimally, sets a new price (i) according to the indexation rule

where 0 < γ < 1 is the degree of indexation to the previous period's domestic inflation rate.

2.4.4. New Keynesian Phillips (NKP) Curve

It follows directly from the price setting structure above that the Home domestic price PH,t, as defined in eqs.(5), is given by PH,t = .8 8 By the law of large numbers, PH ,t–1 is also the average last price of the firms not adjusting prices optimally. Combining the log-linearization of this equation with the result (30) yields the NKP curve

where λ ≡ (1 - øβ).

2.5. Monetary Policy

We assume that the Home Central Bank follows the Taylor-type rule

where ξM,t is a Gaussian i.i.d monetary policy shock and δr is the interest rate smoothing coefficient. Following the new Keynesian procedure, we introduce the output gap into the rule, which is defined as tyt-t, where t is the Home output level under flexible prices.9 9 This rule has usually been adopted in the most previous empirical studies, although some works use instead rules with the output growth Δ yt ≡ yt - yt –1. We do not derive the optimal monetary rule since it is not necessarily used in practice.

2.6. Equilibrium

In this section, we derive the general equilibrium dynamics for the log-linearized version of the model around the steady state, in which the productivity shifters Atand remain constant in their long-run equilibrium levels equal to 1. For sake of simplicity, we follow the literature and assume the same preference parameters and initial wealth conditions for both countries.10 10 For the purpose of estimating the model with Brazilian data, this assumption is not so restrictive, since the parameters for home bias degree and the elasticity of substitution between Home and Foreign goods, given by and µ respectively, do not affect the Foreign economy's dynamics in the small Home country version of the model.

2.6.1. Demand Side: Goods Markets Equilibrium and IS Curves

As explained in subsection (2.2.3), the markets of all goods clear in equilibrium, so that Yt(i) = (i) for i ∈[0, n). Hence, we can substitute eq.(10) into definition (29) in order to get

where we also use the results (5) and (11), along with the definitions (15) and (17). Log-linearizing this result, we get

A deterioration of Home TOT - an increase in st - increases the world demand for Home goods. The size of this effect rises with the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported goods µ and falls with the degree of home bias . Furthermore, Home output increases with the Home and Foreign aggregate consumption ct and . A lower degree of home bias - equivalent to a higher degree of openness - reduces the size of the positive impact of an increase in the Home domestic consumption on the Home output, while increases the size of the positive impact of the Foreign output on the Home output. For closed countries, when = 0, we get ct = yt.

2.6.2. Supply Side: Labor Market Equilibrium and Marginal Costs

The Home labor market equilibrium condition is given by = Lt. Substituting eqs.(14) and (28) into this condition and solving it for real wage, we get . Now, substituting this result into eq. (27) for the real marginal cost and log-linearizing, we get11 11 As explained in (Gali and Monacelli, 2005), the deviations of ut ≡ ln Ut around the steady state are of second order, so that up to a first order approximation we can set ut = 0.

Since this equation determines the Home real marginal cost, which enters into the Home NKP curve (33), it allows us to understand the three sources of inflationary pressure on the Home domestic prices. First, a higher Home output yt or a lower Home productivity at increases, ceteris paribus, Home labor demand and hence pushes Home real wage and marginal cost up. The size of this effect falls with the real wage-elasticity of labor supply, given by the inverse of parameter φ. Second, a higher current Home domestic consumption ct reduces the marginal utility of real wage and thus shrinks the labor supply, pushing real wage and marginal cost up. This effect increases with the habit formation index h and with the inverse elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption σ, since this parameter measures the negative impact of the marginal utility with respect to consumption. Third, the purchase power of the Home wage in terms of Home goods increases with the Home TOT st, pushing the real marginal cost - also measured in terms of Home goods - up. The Home NKP curve (33), complemented by the Home real marginal cost equation (36), fully characterizes the Home economy's supply side. Unlike models for closed economies, there is no more a direct relationship - given a fixed productivity - between output and marginal cost and therefore between output and inflation. This happens because the real marginal cost is also affected by the TOT.in open economies.

2.6.3. Foreign Country's Economy

The Foreign counterparts for eqs.(19), (33), (36), (13), (35), (34) and (26) are given respectively by

In particular, for the small Home country case, when n ~ 0, we can set and .

2.6.4. Canonical Representation

The canonical representation of the general equilibrium dynamics is described by the following sets of equations: (1) eqs.(19) and (37), which relates CPI and domestic inflation; (2) NKP curve (33) along with the marginal cost equation (36) and their Foreign counterparts (38) and (39), which characterize the supply side of Home and Foreign countries respectively; (3) eqs.(13) and (35) and their Foreign counterparts (40) and (41), which characterize the demand side (IS curves) of the Home and Foreign countries respectively; (4) UIP equation (24) or, alternatively, IRS condition (23); (5) monetary policy rules (34) and (42); (5) the equations describing the general equilibrium under flexible prices, since the output gaps

tyt - t and are introduced into the monetary rules, where t and t are the output under flexible prices.12 12 As we saw in subsection (2.2.3), under flexible prices, all Home firms adjust optimally their prices every period according to the pricing rule (31), i.e., as a mark-up over the marginal cost. In addition, they set the same price , since they face identical technological and demand constraints. Therefore, the Home real marginal cost is given by mct ≡ = - ψ. By the same argument, we get = - ψ. These two results, associated to the flexible-price counterparts for equations in the canonical representation, are enough to characterize the flexible-price general equilibrium dynamics for real variables.

3. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

In this section, we calibrate/estimate the structural paramaters with Brazilian data for the Home country and U.S. data for the Foreign country.13 13 We proceed in this way as a first exercise and leave for future research the task of estimating the model with more representative historical series for the Foreign country, which would be the weighted average of the historical series of the main Brazilian financial and trade partners. Next, we test for the relevance of endogenous persistence in the Brazilain economy. Finally, we use our estimates to compute impulse-response functions in order to analyse the effects of structural shocks on the macroeconomic variables' dynamics. As Brazilian economy is small, we have n = 0 in eq.(9), so that α = .

3.1. Calibration and Bayesian Estimation

Parameters and β are calibrated with basis on steady-state relations between endogenous variables. The share of imported goods in the Brazilian aggregate consumption basket, denoted by α, is set to 0.13, which is consistent to the ratio Brazilian imports/GDP and Brazilian net exports/GDP during the sample period.14 14 Denoting by Mt and NXt the Home imports and current account as a proportion of the output, we get NXt = and Mt = , with , where we use definitions (15), the aggregate counterpart for in eqs.(6) and the fact that n = 0 in eq.(9) because Brazilian economy is small. Since St = h( St) = g( St) = 1 in steady state, we can use the results above to get a calibrated value for . The discount factor β is set to 0.91 (annual basis) in order to get approximately the historical mean of the nominal interest rate in the steady state.15 15 Since the parameter β is common to both countries, we set an intermediary value.

Following an increasing part of the empirical literature, we use the Bayesian approach to estimate the other parameters of the model, which works as follows. First, we assume a prior distribution with density p(θ) for the vector θ of structural parameters to be estimated, which summarizes our previous beliefs about the location of these parameters, that is, all information we have in addition to the database YT used in estimation. We follow the usual procedure of assuming that the parameters have independent priors, so that we can specify a marginal prior for each parameter separately. Second, the database YT is used to update the prior distribuition according the Bayes rule, giving rise to the posterior distribution

where L(θ| YT) is the likelihood function. If the posterior is not standard, draws from this distribution can be generated numerically through simulation technics. Third, we compute posterior summary statistics in order to characterize the location of the structural parameters.

We denote by Yt the vector of observed variables used in estimation, which are proxies for the following endogenous variables in the model: the Brazilian and U.S. output yt and , CPI inflation πt and and nominal interest rate rt and , as well as the bilateral real exchange rate qt. The database YT comprises therefore the T-size historical series of the observed variables, which are described in more detail below. Given some initial values for parameters, we use Kalman filter to evaluate the likelikood function in eq.(45). For that, we need first to write the state-space representation for the dynamics of Yt, which is given by a set of two vectorial equations: (1) the state equation for the dynamics of the endogenous (state) variables of the model, which is the reduced-form solution (derived with Sim's algorithm) of the log-linearized structural model and (2) the measurement equation Yt = Xt + wt, which links the observed variables in Yt to the endogenous variables grouped in Xt through a known matrix , where wt is a vector of normally distributed and independent measurement errors. As usual, we assume that wt are independent from the structural shocks εt. To avoid stochastic singulariry in the case where there are more observed variables than shocks, three measurement errors were included in wt, in such a way they can be interpreted as Brazilian and U.S. inflation shocks and a external risk premium shock. Less rigorously, this amounts to add a IID shock to structural eqs. (33), (38) and (24) respectively.

As the posterior distribution in this case is clearly non-standard, we use Metropolis-Hasting algorithm to generate draws from this distribution.16 16 This part is implemented with the use of DYNARE (Matlab version). A detailed explanation of this program is available in http://www.cepremap.cnrs.fr/dynare/. The idea behind this procedure is to simulate a Markov Chain θt, t = 1,2,..., that converges to the posterior distribution. Intuitively, the algorithm works because the transition distribution T(θt| θt-1) of the process is built to make it behave like the stochastic version of a stepwise mode-finding algorithm, always stepping to increase the density but only sommetimes stepping to decrease.17 17 (Carlin et al., 1995) give a very intuitive description of the algorithm. In order to guarantee convergence, posterior simulation uses only the second half of two parallel chains with 120.000 runs. The scale factor was chose to provide an acceptance rate of about 25%-40%. Convergence diagnosis testes in were used to evaluate convergence of the Markov chain to the posterior distribution.

3.2. Data

We estimate the model with quarterly data of the Brazilian and U.S. economies for the period from 1999Q3 to 2005Q3. Structural breaks in Brazilian economy prevent us from using longer series.18 18 The sample period starts at 1999.III with the inflation target regime, after Brazilian exchange rate liberalization. For both countries, the output gap is the detrended (linear) log real GDP (multiplied by 100) and the CPI inflation is the annualized quarterly percentage change in the CPI index. The full IPCA index produced by IBGE is used for Brazil. The U.S. nominal interest rate is the 3-month Treasury Bill annualized percentage period-average daily rate, while the Brazilian nominal interest rate is the annualized percentage period-average daily rate of reference for the 90-day DI-pré swap contract traded in BMF. Real exchange rate series is build with the Brazilian and U.S. period-average log CPI indexes and the period-average log nominal bilateral exchange rate. Data are available in ipeadata, except for Brazilian swaps, which are obtained from Brazilian Central Bank. All variables are demeaned and, if necessary, seasonally adjusted with the X-12 method. The U.S. inflation and nominal interest rate are also detrended with a linear filter. This previous treatment is necessary because the model is not developed to explain linear tendencies and seasonal movements.

3.3. Prior Distributions

The prior distributions reflect our beliefs about the values that the parameters can take. Large prior standard deviations result in diffuse distributions, which means we have little information in addition to the data. On the contrary, small prior standard deviations mean we are confident that the parameters take some value around their prior means. Most earlier attempts to estimate new Keynesian DSGE models with the Bayesian approach use data from developed countries, which have a record of macroeconomic stabilization much longer than the Brazilian economy. Therefore, we seek to specify more diffuse priors that those usually found in the empirical literature, since we figure out it should be much harder to deal with the uncertainty on Brazilian parameters. In setting the prior distribution for a given parameter, we need to make two choices: (1) the parametric distribution and (2) the values for the characteristic parameters of this distribution. In many cases, the choice of the distribution is restricted by the domain in which the parameter can take values. In addition, we can use the Bayesian esimates for other countries as a reference guide. The prior distributions are summarized in Table 1 and their graphs - in grey - are shown in Figure 1, 2 and 3.19 19 The graphs for other parameters can be provided under request.


Beta distributions with mean 0.5 and standard deviation 0.18 were selected for most Home and Foreign parameters constrained on the unit-interval: the autorregressive productivity coeficients ρ and ρ*, the Calvo-stickiness parameters ø and ø*, the interest rate somoothing parameters δr and and the degree of habit formation h. This is a symmetric and fairly diffuse distribution with a 90% interval between 0.20 and 0.80, which reflects our uncertainty about these parameters.20 20 For robustness test, a beta prior with mean 0.7 and standard deviation 0.1 was also used without changing the results significatively. This prior implies a 90% interval bertween 0.52 and 0.85, which is enough large to include the central moments estimates found in previous studies for other countries. The only exception was the use of a uniform distribution between 0 an 1 for the degrees of price indexation γ and γ*, since beta priors yielded very suspicious posterior estimates.

A Gamma distribution was used for the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported goods µ, since we expect a positive value for this parameter. We set a prior mean and standard deviation at 1 and 0.6 respectively. As usual in the literature, the inverse elasticity intertemporal of substitution in consumption σ and the inverse elasticity of labor supply φ are assumed to follow a Normal distribution with prior means and standard deviations such that these elasticities lies on a large 90% interval between 0.55 and 5.63 and between 0.37 and 3.75 respectively.

Following again the literature, we use Normal distributions for the Taylor rules' coefficients regarding inflation and output gap with the prior means set respectively at 1.5 and 0.5. These values are close to the ones commonly used in previous works, such as (Caputo et al., 2005) for Chile. Again, we use larger prior strandard deviations to deal with the uncertainty about these rules in the Brazilian economy. Inverse Gamma distributions are used for the volatility of the shocks.

3.4. Model Comparison

Before analyzing our posterior densities, we estimate and compare four alternative model specifications in order to evaluate the role for endogenous persistence in the Brazilian economy: (1) model with habit formation and price indexation (HF-PI); (2) model only with habit formation (HF); (3) model only with price indexation (PI); (4) model without persistence (WP). The estimated posterior densities for all models are summarized in Table 1. The Bayesian approach allows us to compare rigorously how well two alternatives models mK and mL are fitted to data YT through the ratio between the posterior model probabilities p(mK|YT) and p(mH|YT), which is known as posterior odds POK,H. Using the Bayes rule, we have that

where the density p(YT|mK) = θL(θ| YT,mK) p(θ) dθ is known as the marginal likelihood (ML) of model mK, while p(mK|YT) and p(mK) are, respectively, the posterior and prior probabilities of data YT have been generated by model mK. In sum, posterior odds uses data YT to update our previous beliefs about how much model mK is more likely to explain the data than model mH, which is given by . As we have no previous beliefs, we assume that p(mK) = p(mH). In this case, posterior odds above 1 means that data YT provides information in favor of model mK over mH.

We estimate the log marginal likelihood (ML) by using the simulation-based modified harmonic mean proposed by (Geweke, 1998), which is shown in the last row of Table 1. A very robust finding is that models perform much better with habit formation. The differences in terms of log ML between models HF-PI and PI and between models HF and WP are 18.61 and 20.17 respectively, which translates - with equal prior probabilities - into posterior odds greater than e8. Definitively, habit information is an empirically testifiable property of Brazilian economy's structural models designed for monetary policy analysis. Less strongly, price indexation also improves the fitness to the data. The differences in terms of log ML between models HF-PI and HF and between models PI and WP are 2.79 and 4.35 respectively, which translates into posterior odds around 16 and 77. In some sense, the relatively weaker evidence for price indexation over habit formation in the Brazilian economy is coherent with one of the main findings by (Justiniano and Preston, 2004), which asserts that a robust result across specifications and countries - Australia, Canada and New Zealand - is that the inclusion of price indexation is not validated by the data, while habit formation seem to matter in some cases.

Another important question is to analyze how the introduction of endogenous persistence affects the parameter estimates. Coherent with our previous finding, Table 1 highlights that our estimates are robust to the inclusion of price indexation, while assuming habit formation has two sizable effects on preference parameters estimates. First, it increases both the elasticity of labor supply 1/φ and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption 1/σ. The intuition follows from Euler equation (13), by which these elasticities and habit information index h have opposite effects on the interest rate monetary policy transmission, so that σ and φ must fall when h rises in order the model to reproduce the observed correlation between the interest rate, inflation and output. Second, it also reduces the elasticity of substitution in consumption between domestic and imported goods µ. We can understand this result by having in mind eqs.(21) and (35), as well as the IRS condition (23). Since a higher h rises Brazilian consumption volatility, µ must fall in order to reproduce the observed volatilities of the real exchange rate and Brazilian and U.S. outputs.21 21 In future work, we discuss in more detail the effects of different model assumptions on the parameters estimates.

3.5. Posterior Distribution

Now, we analyze the posterior densities for the model with both habit formation and price indexation (HF-PI), which provides the best fitting to the data. Their statistic summaries are presented in Table 1, while their graphs - in black - are shown in Fures 1, 2 and 3. Two facts are notorious. First, posterior densities are less diffuse than their prior counterparts. Second, the prior and posterior means are in most cases considerably apart one another. Both results suggest that the data contain information capable to update our prior beliefs, although in an extent that varies among parameters. For instance, the data seem to be more informative about Brazilian Calvo price stickiness than about Brazilian monetary policy rule. Other convenient fact is that posterior distributions are roughly symmetric, which makes possible to compare our results with other studies that present different measures of central tendency. Validating the robustness of our results, the estimates for U.S. economy are, in general, consistent to previous empirical works, such as (Rabanal and Rubio-Ramírez, 2001) and (Smets and Woulters, 2004). On the other hand, the lack of similar works for emerging economies prevents from evaluating more accuralety the robustness of our estimates for Brazil.22 22 As far as we are concerned, the only work in this line for a Latin America country is (Caputo et al., 2005).

The posterior mean of the Brazilian Calvo parameter for price stickiness ø is of 0.89, with a 90% confidence interval between 0.83 and 0.97.23 23 Throughout this paper, the 5% and 95% percentiles are, respectively, the lower and upper limits of the 90% confidence intervals. This estimate can be translated into an avarage duration of price contracts superior to two years, so that Brazilian price rigidity would be comparable with that for European and U.S. economies found by (Smets and Woulters, 2004), but higher than those for Australia, Canada and New Zealand found by (Justiniano and Preston, 2004). (Caputo et al., 2005) also estimate a much lower posterior mean for Chile - around 0.12 - although their baseline model includes wage stickiness with estimated Calvo parameter around 0.85, which could explain their weak evidence for price rigidity. The estimated Brazilian price stickiness sounds strange since we would expect more price flexibility in countries with a higher historical level of inflation rates. A possible explanation is that firms setting prices in a relatively more inflationary environment could have a stronger forward-looking behavior, placing more weight on marginal costs farther into the future, so that frequent readjustments would not be necessary.

The posterior mean of the U.S. Calvo parameter for price rigidity ø* is of 0.91, which amounts to a price duration around ten quarters. The posterior density is fairly concentrated around the mean, with a 90% confidence interval between 0.86 and 0.99. These results imply a strong price rigidity for the U.S. economy. They are in line with the median of 0.91 found by (Smets and Woulters, 2004).

The data seem to be very informative with respect to Brasilian and U.S. degrees of price indexation γ and γ*, since posterior distributions are much less diffuse than their prior counterparts. For Brazil, the posterior mean is of 0.44, with a 90% confidence interval between 0.13 and 0.71. Price indexation in Brazil is higher than that observed by (Justiniano and Preston, 2004) for developed small economies. The posterior distribution for the Foreign degree is positively symmetric, with mean of 0.51 and a 90% confidence interval between of 0.09 and 0.91. Consistent to other empirical studies, such as (Rabanal and Rubio-Ramírez, 2001), price indexation seems to be relevant for U.S. economy.

Both Brazilian and U.S. productivity shocks are very persistent, although still stationary. The 90% confidence interval of the U.S productivity autoregressive coefficient ρ* is between 0.95 and 0.99. This result is again in line with (Smets andWoulters, 2004), which estimates basically the same interval. The Brazilian productivity shocks are fairly less persistent, with a 90% confidence interval for the Brazilian autorregressive productivity parameter ρ between 0.56 and 0.95.

The posterior mean of the habit formation degree h is of 0.69, with a 90% confidence interval between 0.55 and 0.81. In principle, this result suggests the empirical relevance of habit formation for Brazil, although we must be cautious since this parameter is, by construction, commom for both countries and therefore its estimate is influenced by U.S. data.24 24 We are currently working on a model with different preference parameters for Home and Foeign countries. (Justiniano and Preston, 2004) found a fairly close posterior mean of 0.79 for Canada, although significatively lower estimates for Australia and New Zealand. (Caputo et al., 2005) found a slightly higher estimate for Chile.

As we estimate a small-economy version of the model, the elasticity of substitution in consumption between imported and domestic goods µ matters only for Brazilian economy. We estimate for this parameter a posterior mean of 0.06, which is much lower than the estimates for other countries. (Caputo et al., 2005) found a posterior mean around 0.56 for Chile, while (Justiniano and Preston, 2004) estimates median higher than 0.2 for Australia, Canada and New Zealand. Despite this counter-evidence, the Brazilian data seem to be very informative with respect to this parameter as its posterior mean is pratically unaffected by the use of alternative prior distributions. In addition, Table 1 shows that different models specifications also yields low estimates. The relatively low value for this parameter would indicate that Brazilian output and imports have different composition and therefore a very low substitubility, implying that the terms of trade channel of monetary policy transmission is not so relevant for Brazilian economy.

The posterior mean of the inverse elasticity of labor supply φ is of 0.77, which means 1/φ equal to 1.30. The international evidence suggests lower elasticities. For instance, (Smets and Woulters, 2004) with U.S. data and (Liu, 2005) with New Zealand data found posterior medians for φ around 2.90 and 2.60 respectively. This result is consistent with the expected higher responsiveness of the labor supply to wages in the countries with lower per-capital personal income, since economic theory postulates that poor workers are less reluctant in allocating free time to work. However, this is another preference parameter shared by Brazilian and U.S. economies, so that its estimate is influenced by U.S. data.

The posterior mean of the inverse elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption σ is of 2.09, which means 1/σ equal to 0.48. Brazilian aggregate demand is responsive to changes in real interest rate, so that the conventional interest rate channel on monetary policy transmission is effective in the Brazilian economy. The data are fairly informative with respect to this parameter, with the posterior and prior means very far from each other. Although our estimates be slightly above those usually found in earlier empirical works, the great variability that characterize these results does not allow a definitive conclusion.

The estimates of the Brazilian Taylor rule's coefficients for inflation and output gap, denoted by δπ and δy, seem to be consistent to the inflation target regime implemented during the sample period: the posterior 90% confidence intervals lie entirely on the positive line, so that monetary policy reacts countercyclically to inflationary pressures. In addition, the estimates are fairly comparable to those for countries with the same monetary regime: we found posterior means around 1.05 and 0.82 for δπ and δy, while the corresponding values in (Caputo et al., 2005) are around 1.18 and 0.28 respectively. The posterior mean of the Brazilian interest rate smoothing coefficient δr is of 0.59, which is lower than the posterior mean of the U.S. corresponding parameter. Thus, Brazilian data does not suggest a very high persistence for the interest rate.

The posterior mean of the U.S. interest rate smoothing coefficient is of 0.81, with a 90% confidence interval between 0.72 and 0.91. However, this persistence is lower than that found by (Smets and Woulters, 2004), which get a posterior median of 0.91. The U.S. coefficients for inflation and output gap and are of 2.10 and 0.53 respectively, implying that U.S. monetary policy reacts more to inflation than to output gap. These results are not comparable to those found by (Smets and Woulters, 2004) because they use a different monetary rule.

3.6. Impulse-Response Functions

Figure 4 shows the impulse-response (IR) functions for Brazilian endogenous variables in response to unit-size positive temporary productivity, monetary policy and inflation shocks.25 25 For lack of space, IR functions to U.S. productivity shocks and risk premium are omitted, since the associated 5%-95% posterior intervals are much larger than for the other shocks. In addition, as explained in subsection (3.1), risk premium shocks were introduced into the model in an ad hoc way, so that we are very suspicious about the dynamic effects produced by these shocks. Also for lack of space, we omit the graphs of the IR functions of U.S. endogenous variables, which can be provided under request. The solid middle line is the mean IR function, while the dotted upper and lower lines are the limits of a 90% confidence interval. As Brazilian economy is small, domestic shocks do not affect U.S. variables. Stationarity makes all variables converge to their steady-state levels in the long-run. As a result of our estimates for the autoregressive coefficients, productivity shocks have very persistent effects on the economy. On the other hand, monetary policy and inflation shocks are little persistent. Consumption and output responses are humped-shaped because, under habit formation, agents smooth both the level and the changes in consumption.


3.6.1. Brazilian Productivity Shock

The first row in Figure 4 shows the effects of a positive Brazilian productivity shock. For a given level of output, higher productivity shrinks labor demand, pushing real wage and marginal cost down. Firms allowed to adjust prices react by cutting domestic prices in order to maintain markup unaltered. Consequently, the TOT rises around 1% on impact, which improves Brazilian goods' competitiveness. In addition, despite the small CPI inflation on impact, monetary policy reacts to the negative output gap by cutting nominal interest rate.26 26 The negative effect of this shock on the output level under flexible prices is stronger than under sticky prices, so that output gap diminishes. As a result, domestic consumption goes up in response to lower expected future real interest rates. As a joint effect of higher domestic demand and lower relative price, Brazilian output rises around 0.2% on impact. On the other hand, Brazilian currency depreciates around 1% on impact in response to the expected period of monetary loosening. The consequent higher prices of imported goods not only reinforces the increase in TOT, but also explains the small CPI inflation observed on impact, despite the fall of domestic prices. One period after, Brazilian currency stabilizes, while domestic prices keeps falling, causing a CPI deflation. Over time, as more firms adjust prices and the shock is amortized, economy returns gradually to steady state, which takes more than 20 quarters because since productivity shocks are very persistent.

3.6.2. Inflation Shocks

The second row in Figure 4 shows the effects of a positive Brazilian domestic inflation shock. The TOT falls around 0.5% on impact, worsening Brazilian goods's competitiveness. In addition, the monetary policy reaction to inflation leads domestic consumption to decline in response to higher future expected real interest rates. The consequent fall of the output around 0.08% shrinks the labor demand, while the lower domestic consumption increases the labor supply. Both effects all together push real wage and marginal cost down. However, the downward pressure on labor market is not so strong to annulate the primmary and direct effect of the shock, so that a CPI inflation around 1% is observed on impact. Despite the inflation persistence, monetary policy is effective in fighting inflation, which is almost entirely eliminated two periods after the shock. In consequence, monetary policy starts getting looser quickly, which pushes consumption, output and real wage up. Due to endogenous and monetary policy persistence, convergence of real variables to steady state takes around five quarters more than inflation.

The third row in Figure 4 shows the effects of a positive U.S. inflation shock. On impact, U.S monetary policy reacts strongly by raising nominal interest rate, pushing U.S. consumption and output down. As the shock is partially compensated by the nagative impact of the recession on real wage and marginal cost, it produces only a small CPI inflation. Over time, as inflation gradually falls and households expect lower real interest rates, the output increases and economy returns to stady state.

On impact, U.S. inflation and Brazilian currency depreciation - in response to U.S. monetary tightening - cause an increase in Brazilian CPI index and TOT around 0.2% and 2% respectively. Despite the improved world competitiveness, the antiinflationary reaction of the Brazilian monetary policy causes a small recession, which pushes real wage down. However, real marginal cost - measured in terms of domestic goods - rises with the higher TOT, leading firms to increase domestic prices. Monetary policy is again effective in neutralizing the effect of the on inflation. Just after the shock, Brazilian currency has a strong appreciation, pushing TOT down, while monetary policy gets looser with the decline in inflation, allowing the economy to start recovering from the recession.

3.6.3. Monetary Policy Shocks

The fourth row in Figure 4 shows the effects of a positive Brazilian monetary policy shock. On impact, Brazilian currency appreciates, impairing the Brazilian goods' competitiveness since the TOT decreases around 1.5%. Simultaneouly, domestic consumption falls is response to higher future expected real interest rates. Both effects impact negatively on output, which falls around 0.2%. In consequence, labor demand shrinks, pushing both real wage down, so that firms start cutting prices. On the other hand, both domestic deflation and currency appreciation make CPI index fall around 0.25% on impact. Just after the shock, the nominal exchange rate overshoots and then converge quickly to steady state. This explains the positive CPI inflation before the price stabilization. In addition, the currency depreciation reinforces the positive effect of domestic deflation on TOT, so that Brazilian goods' competitiveness starts improving. At the same time, monetary policy gets looser in response to price stabilization and negative output gap, which in turn expands domestic consumption. This scenario allows the economy to recover from the recession. In general, the convergence takes around six quarters, so that the effects of the shock are relatively little persistent.

The fifth row in Figure 4 shows the effects of a positive U.S. monetary shock. On impact, U.S. households contract consumption in response to higher future expected real interest rates. The consequent fall in U.S. output pushes U.S. real wage and marginal cost down, resulting in a CPI deflation. Endogenous and monetary policy persistence mechanisms makes the nominal interest rate - and with it the rest of the economy - converge gradually to steady state, which takes around ten quarters to complete.

As a net effect of U.S. deflation and Brazilian currency depreciation caused directly by the shock, the TOT increases around 3% with the higher domestic prices of imported goods. Despite the improved competitiveness, Brazilian antiinflationary monetary policy is strong enough to cause a small fall in output. Although real wage falls on impact and remains pratically close to equilibrum three quarters after the shock, its purchase power in terms of domestic goods increases with the higher TOT, so that the real marginal cost - in terms of domestic goods - increases with the shock. Therefore, Brazilian firms react to expected positive future real marginal costs by rising domestic prices, which gives rise to a domestic inflation that neutralizes the negative effect of the imported goods deflation on CPI inflation along the convergence period.

4. CONCLUSION

With Brazilian data for the inflation target period, we use the Bayesian approach to estimate alternative new Keynesian DSGE model specifications with respect to the existence of two endogenous persistence mechanisms widely supported by the empirical literature: habit formation and price indexation. Under many aspects, our results are in line with most empirical studies for other small open economies. We conclude for the relavance of habit formation, which therefore must be introduced into Brazilian economy's structural models designed to monetary policy analysis. However, our evidence is strikingly less suggestive with respect to price indexation. Given the high weight of administered prices in Brazilian price indexes, we would expect a more robust result validating the importance of this mechanism, although we must be cautious once Brazilian historical series are still relatively short. A suggestion for future research would be estimate a model with both price and wage stickiness and indexation, which is an alternative route to deal with nominal persistence.

The analysis of impulse-response functions yields promising qualitative results. In general, structural shocks impact on endogenous variables in the right direction, so that the model seems to be helpful as a tool for monetary policy analysis in the Brazilian economy. In addition, habit formation allows the model to reproduce the observed hump-shaped dynamics response of consumption and output, while price indexation delivers more persistence to inflation. However, the magnitude and persistence of the shocks are somewhat unrealistic. In order to reproduce actual Brazilian macroeconomic time series more accurately, models with other structural assumptions must be estimated, such as credit frictions, incomplete pass-through, non-tradability, government and so on.

Bibliography

Brooks, S. & Gelman, A. (1998). General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 7(4):434–455.

Caputo, R., Liendo, F., &Medina, J. (2005). New keynesian models for chile in the inflation target period: A structural investigation. preliminary version. Central Bank of Chile.

Carlin, J., Gelman, A., Rubin, D., & Stern, A. (1995). Bayesian data analysis. Texts in Statistical Science.

Chari, V., Kehoe, P., & Mcgrattan, E. (2002). Can sticky price models generate volatile and persistence real exchange rate? Review of Economic Studies, 69(3):533–563.

Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., &Evans, C. (2005). Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects ofa shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 113:1–45.

Gali, J. & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(3):707–734.

Geweke, J. (1998). Using simulation methods for bayesian econometrics models: Inference, development and communications. manuscript. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Justiniano, A. & Preston, B. (2004). Small open economy dsge models: Specification, estimation and model fit. Manuscript, Columbia University.

Liu, P. (2005). A small new keynesian model of the new zealand economy. manuscript. Reserve Bank of New Zealand.

Rabanal, P. & RubioRamírez, J. F. (2001). Comparing new keynesian models of the business cycle: A bayesian approach. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper.

Smets, F. & Woulters, R. (2004). Comparing shocks and frictions in u.s. and euro area business cycles: A bayesian dsge. European Central Bank, 391.

A. APPENDIX



Clique aqui para ampliar

Clique aqui para ampliar

  • Brooks, S. & Gelman, A. (1998). General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 7(4):434455.
  • Caputo, R., Liendo, F., &Medina, J. (2005). New keynesian models for chile in the inflation target period: A structural investigation. preliminary version. Central Bank of Chile.
  • Carlin, J., Gelman, A., Rubin, D., & Stern, A. (1995). Bayesian data analysis. Texts in Statistical Science
  • Chari, V., Kehoe, P., & Mcgrattan, E. (2002). Can sticky price models generate volatile and persistence real exchange rate? Review of Economic Studies, 69(3):533563.
  • Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., &Evans, C. (2005). Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects ofa shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 113:145.
  • Gali, J. & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(3):707734.
  • Geweke, J. (1998). Using simulation methods for bayesian econometrics models: Inference, development and communications. manuscript. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
  • Justiniano, A. & Preston, B. (2004). Small open economy dsge models: Specification, estimation and model fit. Manuscript, Columbia University.
  • Liu, P. (2005). A small new keynesian model of the new zealand economy. manuscript. Reserve Bank of New Zealand.
  • Rabanal, P. & RubioRamírez, J. F. (2001). Comparing new keynesian models of the business cycle: A bayesian approach. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper.
  • Smets, F. & Woulters, R. (2004). Comparing shocks and frictions in u.s. and euro area business cycles: A bayesian dsge. European Central Bank, 391.
  • *
    I am grateful to Ajax Moreira (IPEA), Marco Bonomo (FGV-RJ), Maria Cristina Terra (FGV- RJ) and René Garcia (Universidade de Montreal) for useful comments.
  • 1
    New Keynesian models assume that nominal short-term interest rate is the monetary policy instrument, so that money supply is endogenous. Thus, we follow the literature and do not put money demand into preferences explicitly.
  • 2
    We minimize
    and
    subject to eqs.(3).
  • 3
    Note that a change in
    n alters
    α even if the degree of home bias
    remains constant.
  • 4
    In log-linearizing the particular model specification with symmetric preferences, we must set
    =
    *.
  • 5
    This result is very intuitive when we note that the degree of home bias is inversely related to the degree of trade openness.
  • 6
    We assume that firms not adjusting prices optimally also meet demand, so that
    Yt
    +s(
    i) =
    (
    i) for any s.
  • 7
    We suppress the index i because all firms adjusting prices optimally take the same decision, since they face identical current and expected future marginal costs.
  • 8
    By the law of large numbers,
    PH
    ,t–1 is also the average last price of the firms not adjusting prices optimally.
  • 9
    This rule has usually been adopted in the most previous empirical studies, although some works use instead rules with the output growth Δ
    yt
    yt -
    yt
    –1.
  • 10
    For the purpose of estimating the model with Brazilian data, this assumption is not so restrictive, since the parameters for home bias degree and the elasticity of substitution between Home and Foreign goods, given by
    and
    µ respectively, do not affect the Foreign economy's dynamics in the small Home country version of the model.
  • 11
    As explained in (Gali and Monacelli, 2005), the deviations of
    ut ≡ ln
    Ut around the steady state are of second order, so that up to a first order approximation we can set
    ut = 0.
  • 12
    As we saw in subsection (2.2.3), under flexible prices, all Home firms adjust optimally their prices every period according to the pricing rule (31), i.e., as a mark-up over the marginal cost. In addition, they set the same price
    , since they face identical technological and demand constraints. Therefore, the Home real marginal cost is given by
    mct
    = -
    ψ. By the same argument, we get
    = -
    ψ. These two results, associated to the flexible-price counterparts for equations in the canonical representation, are enough to characterize the flexible-price general equilibrium dynamics for real variables.
  • 13
    We proceed in this way as a first exercise and leave for future research the task of estimating the model with more representative historical series for the Foreign country, which would be the weighted average of the historical series of the main Brazilian financial and trade partners.
  • 14
    Denoting by
    Mt and
    NXt the Home imports and current account as a proportion of the output, we get
    NXt =
    and
    Mt =
    , with
    , where we use definitions (15), the aggregate counterpart for
    in eqs.(6) and the fact that
    n = 0 in eq.(9) because Brazilian economy is small. Since
    St =
    h(
    St) =
    g(
    St) = 1 in steady state, we can use the results above to get a calibrated value for
    .
  • 15
    Since the parameter
    β is common to both countries, we set an intermediary value.
  • 16
    This part is implemented with the use of DYNARE (Matlab version). A detailed explanation of this program is available in
  • 17
    (Carlin et al., 1995) give a very intuitive description of the algorithm.
  • 18
    The sample period starts at 1999.III with the inflation target regime, after Brazilian exchange rate liberalization.
  • 19
    The graphs for other parameters can be provided under request.
  • 20
    For robustness test, a beta prior with mean 0.7 and standard deviation 0.1 was also used without changing the results significatively. This prior implies a 90% interval bertween 0.52 and 0.85, which is enough large to include the central moments estimates found in previous studies for other countries.
  • 21
    In future work, we discuss in more detail the effects of different model assumptions on the parameters estimates.
  • 22
    As far as we are concerned, the only work in this line for a Latin America country is (Caputo et al., 2005).
  • 23
    Throughout this paper, the 5% and 95% percentiles are, respectively, the lower and upper limits of the 90% confidence intervals.
  • 24
    We are currently working on a model with different preference parameters for Home and Foeign countries.
  • 25
    For lack of space, IR functions to U.S. productivity shocks and risk premium are omitted, since the associated 5%-95% posterior intervals are much larger than for the other shocks. In addition, as explained in subsection (3.1), risk premium shocks were introduced into the model in an ad hoc way, so that we are very suspicious about the dynamic effects produced by these shocks. Also for lack of space, we omit the graphs of the IR functions of U.S. endogenous variables, which can be provided under request.
  • 26
    The negative effect of this shock on the output level under flexible prices is stronger than under sticky prices, so that output gap diminishes.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      06 Feb 2009
    • Date of issue
      Sept 2008
    Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: rbe@fgv.br